The Cost-Effectiveness of Zero-energy and Near Zero-energy Homes in Washington State

Item

Title (dcterms:title)
Eng The Cost-Effectiveness of Zero-energy and Near Zero-energy Homes in Washington State
Date (dcterms:date)
2013
Creator (dcterms:creator)
Eng Beaman, Floyd
Subject (dcterms:subject)
Eng Environmental Studies
extracted text (extracttext:extracted_text)
THE COST-EFFECTIVENESS OF ZERO-ENERGY AND
NEAR ZERO-ENERGY HOMES IN WASHINGTON STATE

by
Floyd Beaman

A Thesis
Submitted in partial fulfillment
of the requirement for the degree of
Master in Environmental Studies
The Evergreen State College
June 2013


 

This Thesis for the Master of Environmental Studies Degree
by
Floyd Beaman

has been approved for
The Evergreen State College
by

Edward A. Whitesell
Member of the Faculty

Date

 


 

ABSTRACT
The Cost-Effectiveness of Zero-Energy and
Near Zero-Energy Homes in Washington State
Floyd Beaman
Zero-energy buildings achieve a net-zero use of electricity from the grid or from
any source that is non-renewable. Such buildings are significant in that they provide an
opportunity for a sustainable energy future. Currently, buildings consume 40% of total
U.S. energy. Thus, a reduction in this sector could have a significant impact on our
energy consumption as a whole. While the building sector includes both commercial and
residential buildings, this thesis focuses on residential buildings in Washington State. As
of now, the technology is available to build such homes, but the question remains
whether it is cost-effective. A number of factors come into play when determining costeffectiveness, such as climate, type of renewable energy, cost of energy by location, etc.
The purpose of this research is to determine the cost-effectiveness of modeled zeroenergy homes in nine locations throughout Washington. While zero-energy homes are the
end goal, several levels of energy efficiency are analyzed along the path to net zero.
“BEopt” (Building Energy Optimization software) was used as the primary tool. The
findings show that as energy efficiency increases, zero-energy homes become less costeffective. Additionally, as energy efficiency increases, the return on investment
decreases. The greatest determinant of cost-effectiveness, in both cases, is the substantial
cost of photovoltaic systems, which were used to produce the renewable energy for all
zero-energy homes modeled in this thesis. Since the cost-effectiveness analysis provided
no distinct answer to whether zero-energy homes are cost-effective, compared to a
similar conventional home, the return on investment was used as a proxy. It was
concluded that homes on the path to net zero are cost-effective (i.e., provide utility bill
savings that cover the increase in energy efficiency costs), up to the point at which
photovoltaic is implemented, which represents an average of 34.3% energy efficiency.


 

 

 

TABLE OF CONTENTS
LIST OF FIGURES

iv

LIST OF TABLES

v

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

vi

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS

vii

1. INTRODUCTION

1

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

6

Defining Net Zero-Energy Homes

7

Understanding the Current Paradigm

22

Technological Feasibility

29

3. METHODS

40

BEopt and Modeling Cost Optimal Designs

44

BEopt Inputs

52

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis and ROI

57

4. RESULTS

68

5. ANALYSIS

77

6. DISCUSSION

96

7. CONCLUSION

106

REFERENCES

110


 

iii
 

 

 

LIST OF FIGURES
1. Overview of Possible Renewable Supply Options

12

2. Sample Results Showing all Points in the Neighborhood of the
Least-Cost Curve

43

3. Conceptual Plot of the Least-Cost Path to a ZEH

47

4. Optimization with Multiple Simulation Programs

50

5. Graphical Representation of the Modeled ZEH

53

6. BEopt Input Selection Screenshot

55

7. Locations for Modeled Zero-Energy Homes in Washington State

57

8. Present Value Cost Formula

63

9. Least-Cost-Curve for Nine Home Locations in Washington State

69

10. Annualized Utility Bills for Nine Locations at Benchmark

75

11. Annualized Utility Bills for Nine Locations at Max Energy Savings

75

12. BEopt Input Screen Indicating the Ingredients (Inputs)
Used for each Location

79

13. Cost-Effectiveness Ratios for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

81

14. Cost-Effectiveness for Homes on the Path to Net Zero in Washington State

83

15. Average ROI Index for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

87

16. ROI Index Calculated for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

88

17. Adjusted Cost-Effectiveness for Homes on the Path to Net Zero

91

18. ROI Index (5% Discount Rate) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

93


 

iv
 

 

 

LIST OF TABLES
1. Annualized Energy-Related Costs for Nine locations on the Path to Net Zero

71

2. Total Marginal Costs ($/%) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

71

3. Annualized Utility Bills ($/yr.) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

74

4. Cost-Effectiveness Ratios ($/%) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

80

5. Net Present Value of Total Utility Bill Savings for Nine Locations on the Path
to Net Zero

85

6. Return on Investment for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

86

7. Total Costs — 30% Tax Credit for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

89

8. CERs Adjusted for 30% Tax Credit for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero 90
9. ROI Index (1% Discount Rate) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

92

10. ROI Index (5% Discount Rate) for Nine Locations on the Path to Net Zero

93


 

v
 

 

 

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I would like to express my deep gratitude to my thesis reader, Dr. Edward
Whitesell for his valuable and constructive suggestions during the writing process of this
thesis. His willingness to give his time so generously has been very much appreciated. I
would also like to thank the Master of Environmental Studies Program at The Evergreen
State College for the opportunity to develop my interests and conduct this research. My
grateful thanks are also extended to my wife, my family, and my friends for their support
and encouragement throughout my study.


 

vi
 

 

 

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS/ACRONYMS

BAB

Building America Benchmark

BEopt

Building Energy Optimization

BPS

Building Performance Simulation

CBA

Cost-Benefit Analysis

CEA

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis

CER

Cost-Effectiveness Ratio

DOE

Department of Energy

DOE2

Department of Energy Building Energy Analysis Program

EISA

Energy Independence and Security Act

EPBD

Energy Performance of Buildings Directive

GHG

Green House Gas

HERS

Home Energy Rating System

HPH

High Performance Homes

HVAC

Heating, Ventilation, Air Conditioning

IECC

International Energy Conservation Code

IPCC

International Panel Climate Change

kW

Kilowatt

KWh

Kilowatt Hour

LC-ZEB

Life Cycle Zero-Energy Building

MWh

Megawatt Hour

NREL

National Renewable Energy Laboratory


 

vii
 

 

 

NZEH

Near Net Zero-Energy Home

PPMV

Parts Per Million by Volume

PV

Photovoltaic

ROI

Return on Investment

SIP

Structurally Insulated Panels

TMY3

Typical Meteorological Year Weather Data 3rd edition

TRNSYS

Transient System Simulation Tool

ZEB

Zero-Energy Building

ZEH

Net Zero-Energy Home


 

viii
 

 

 

Introduction

Currently, 40% of the energy used worldwide is being consumed in buildings
(Kolokotsa et al. 2011). In the United States, buildings are responsible for 39% of energy
consumption, 68% of electricity use, and 38% of the carbon dioxide emissions found in
the atmosphere (Srinivasan et al. 2012). The U.S. residential sector alone accounts for
20% of national energy consumption, 35% of electricity use, and 18% of all greenhouse
gas emissions (Danny 2009). As the population continues to grow, the energy usage in
the building sector is expected to rapidly increase. At the same time, the evidence for
global climate change and for the impacts of greenhouse gas emissions are increasingly
calamitous. The fourth assessment report by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change (IPCC) shows that 11 of the 12 years between 1995 and 2006 were the warmest
years in the record of global surface temperature (since 1850) (IPCC 2007). The
consequences for this century if we continue “business as usual” could be drastic.
However, at the same time, the IPCC is very optimistic about the ability of the building
sector to reduce carbon dioxide emissions through energy efficiency (Verbruggen et al.
2011). A report by the McKinsey Global Institute found that the U.S. could reduce
energy use in new and existing buildings by more than 25% by 2020 with measures that
pay for themselves in less than 10 years (ASE 2010). Additionally, with the global
building sector accounting for over 1/3 of the global energy consumed, this is fast
becoming a very viable option in terms of working towards a clean and sustainable
future.


 

1
 

 

 

The objective of this thesis is to determine the cost-effectiveness of building
highly energy efficiency buildings known as zero-energy homes in the state of
Washington. In doing so, Building Energy Optimization (BEopt) software, were used to
model a home design on the path to achieving net zero-energy efficiency for nine
locations throughout Washington State. The cost data for these homes was then analyzed
to determine the cost effectiveness per unit of energy efficiency as well the return on
investment provided by a reduction in utility bills over the life of the mortgage. This
research provides insight into the current technological and economical feasibility of
zero-energy homes.
The findings presented in this thesis are significant in that it is now necessary that
we identify and become acquainted with every avenue of carbon mitigation and energy
efficiency, particularly those that can be done quickly and cost-effectively first. The
scope of this paper is limited to energy efficiency in the residential building sector, but
the ideas and concepts could be extrapolated to all built environments. Given the benefits
that zero-energy buildings provide, this concept has received special attention around the
world. Not only do such buildings provide a more sustainable future, but they can also
provide specific benefits for the consumer. Through purchasing or building a zero-energy
home, the consumer achieves a reduction in total net monthly cost of living and becomes
protected from the future increase in non-renewable energy costs. In some cases, zeroenergy buildings may produce more energy than is consumed, in which case,
homeowners may receive payment for exports to the grid, depending on where they live.
If this were the case, it would make sense for someone looking to invest in a new home to
consider a zero-energy building. The technology is already available to contstruct net

 

2
 

 

 

zero-energy buildings (ZEBs), but the question remains whether it is currently costeffective for the average consumer to consider investing in this alternative. While the
price of purchasing a zero-energy home is likely to have more upfront costs than a
conventional home, there is a possiblilty that the initial increase in cost could be
reimbursed during the life of the mortgage (typically 30-40 years). In answering these
questions, we deploy the use of cost-effectiveness analysis and return on investment
analysis to compare zero-energy homes (ZEH) and near zero-energy homes (NZEH) to
similar conventional homes. The findings presented in this thesis suggest that as energy
efficiency increases, energy efficient homes become less cost effective. It is also the case
that as energy efficiency increases, the return on investment decreases. Additionally, the
findings show that the greatest determinant of cost-effectiveness, in both cases, is the
substantial cost of photovoltaic systems (PV), which were used to produce the renewable
energy for all zero-energy homes modeled in this thesis. Thus, if the price of PV were to
come down or if financial incentives were provided to lower the overall costs of PV,
zero-energy homes would become more cost-effective as well. Nevertheless, the results
show that energy efficient homes on the path to net zero are cost-effective until the point
at which the marginal cost of energy savings equals the cost of producing PV energy, at
an average of 34.3% energy efficiency. This suggests that the cost-effectiveness of ZEHs
will mirror that of PV into the future.
In determining the cost-effectiveness of zero-energy homes, it is first necessary to
begin with an indepth review of the current literature. This provides the background
needed to understand the current state of research as well as setting the stage for the
research presented in this thesis. Much of the literature focuses on understanding and

 

3
 

 

 

defining what it is to be a zero-energy home. This includes specific definitions as well as
studies on the technological feasibility and applications of such homes. Additionally, a
look into the current paradigm describes the political, social, and economic barriers of
implementing ZEHs and why they have not begun to take hold.
After reviewing the literature, the next chapter covers the methods used in
conducting the research and analysis presented within these pages. As menetioned above,
BEopt software was used to model home designs on the path to net zero for nine
locations throughout Washington State. BEopt generated cost data for each location at
several points along the path to net zero. A Benchmark home, representing a typical
convnetional home, was used as the reference case in which the modeled homes were
compared to. This cost data was then analyzed in the following chapter, using costeffectiveness analysis and return on investment analysis. Utilizing these two methods of
analysis, one is able to ascertain how cost-effective each ZEH or NZEH is at each point
along the path to 100% energy efficiency. One is also able to see at which point
purchasing an energy efficient home can one expect to see a complete return on
investment over the life of the mortgage. The return on investment is used as a proxy for
cost-effectiveness since it does a better job of comparing the cost versus benefits than
does the cost-effectivness analysis. Thus, a home that achieves an ROI equal to 1,
represents a home that is able to completely offset the additional increase in cost due to
increases in energy efficiency through the reduction in utility bills over the life of the
mortgage.
Lastly, a discussion of the importance of building codes in relation to improving
our nation’s energy efficiency in the building sector is presented. It may be that market

 

4
 

 

 

forces are yet unwilling to promote the implementation of energy efficient buildings,
especially with low cost fossil fuels being the primary energy source for the world.
Nevertheless, building codes provide a tried and true method of systematically
implementing energy effciency as we move into the future. Thus, building codes may
provide the best mode of implementing energy efficient measures, particularly those that
are already cost-effecttive.


 

5
 

 

 

Literature Review

Advancements in photovoltaic and efficient building technologies are now
proving, after several decades, that it is technologically feasible to build a home that uses
net zero-energy. Nevertheless, there is still much uncertainty pertaining to the
implementation and economic feasibility of zero-energy homes (ZEH). Much of what we
know currently has come out of experimental studies in which ZEHs are built and
observed to determine their annual energy demand and supply. These feasibility studies
provide great insight into the functionality and possibilities of ZEHs, but do not answer
the question of how we can build such homes in a cost effective way. Since it could be
assumed that cost is one of the greatest barriers of ZEH implementation, a greater
understanding of what it takes to design, build, and operate these types of homes in a cost
effective manner is needed before we can expect to see such homes compete for a share
of the market place. In reviewing the literature, I cover the most common definitions of
what it means for a home to be zero energy. I also analyze the current market and
institutional paradigms as well as review the technological feasibility. Lastly, how this
research and the current body of literature contribute to a more sustainable future is
explored.

Defining Net Zero-Energy Homes
Currently, there is no nationally or internationally agreed upon definition of what
it means for a home to be zero-energy. Nevertheless, this major impediment has been
recognized and effort is being put forth to define the parameters and standards of what a

 

6
 

 

 

zero-energy home will look like and to establish a consistent framework for all zeroenergy buildings. In fact, zero-energy buildings have already been discussed in the U.S.’s
Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007 (EISA 2007) and in Europe with the
recast of the Directive on Energy Performance of Buildings (EPBD) (ASE 2010). Much
of this initial attention has been focused in the commercial arena, but the same concepts
and goals apply. In essence, a zero-energy home could be achieved by taking a
conventional home and adding a very large solar array, or any renewable energy source,
that would offset the home’s energy use through its renewable energy generation. For
example, if the goal were only to achieve net zero energy, and an installed photovoltaic
system delivers more energy than a home uses, then this home is potentially a “net zeroenergy home” under a very loose standard. Thus, the purpose behind building a zeroenergy home or the goals of a zero-energy home must be considered before a given
definition can be settled upon. So, in many cases, the definition or type of zero-energy
home will be largely dependent on the individual project and its objectives. It is with this
understanding that we can define several different types of zero-energy homes.
With no prior understanding of the potentials of zero-energy homes, one might
envision a compact minimalist hut set remotely off the grid. Several solar panels and a
few golf cart batteries, to store the excess energy, would be tucked away to provide this
self-sustaining home with some of the little energy it would need. Although these types
of homes are definitely zero energy, they should really be considered as the jumping off
point for the modern day zero-energy home. That is to say, they were simply an
intermediate step on the path towards the true potential of zero-energy that can be
achieved through net metering. In simple terms, net metering uses the power grid like a

 

7
 

 

 

massive battery. All the excess energy that the home produces through its renewable
energy generation is exported to the grid to be used by others, since it must be used as it
is being generated. This output is accounted for like money in a bank account, to be used
at a later time. For example, at night and during the dark winter months when PV
(photovoltaic) generation is lacking or non-existent, a home can hypothetically import the
energy it produced back, thus resulting in a net-balance. It is with this technology that we
are beginning to see the potential of zero-energy homes unleashed. Beforehand, all excess
energy must have been stored in batteries or used as it was being generated. That was
until 1983, when Minnesota enacted the first net-metering law in the world (DSIRE
2012) So, if you wanted to put a PV system on your home, economically it wouldn’t have
been feasible given the immense amount of batteries needed. Unless your goal was to be
off the grid, in which case you probably don’t require much energy to begin with.
Although off-grid ZEHs are truly zero-energy, they are not practical for the purposes of
this thesis. If we are to work towards zero-energy homes on a massive scale, it is
necessary that they be connected to the grid and able to utilize net metering. Thus, from
now on, all zero-energy homes referred to in this thesis as “ZEH” will refer to any net
zero-energy home and those denoted, as” NZEH” will be considered nearly net zeroenergy homes. These latter are homes on the path towards net zero, not to be confused
with homes that have achieved a net zero standing. Separately, “ZEB” will be used to
denote any zero-energy building (i.e., not just residential buildings), although the focus of
this thesis is on zero-energy homes. Lastly, photovoltaic (PV) is consistently referred to
in this thesis as the primary source of renewable energy generation for ZEHs. This is
because of its general acceptance as the most cost-effective form of renewable energy, its

 

8
 

 

 

widespread implementation, compatibility with net metering, as well as its inclusion in
most building performance simulation (BPS) software programs, including BEopt, the
program used in this thesis.
With this in mind, the heart of defining zero-energy homes comes down to the
different methods of calculating the “zero” balance i.e., “a condition that is satisfied when
weighted supply meets or exceeds weighted demand over a period of time, nominally a
year” (Sartori et al. 2012, p. 222). This balance is influenced by a variety of measures and
each must be taken into account when defining the net zero home. For example, one
might select end-use energy, CO2 emissions, energy, or cost of energy as the metric of
balance. If one of these is given priority over the other or weighted more heavily, then
this will impact the balance calculation methodology and ultimately how we define the
home. Torcellini et al. (2006) provide an overview of the different ZEB designs and how
specific objectives can determine the type of ZEH. Torcellini et al (2006) is considered
the first publication to document and discuss the different zero-energy definitions and is
often cited in publications on ZEBs. Additional research concluded that the definitions
proposed by Torcellini are being continually used in this field of reseach, particularly by
the Department of Energy (DOE) and the National Renewable Energy Laboratory
(NREL). The definitions that are proposed reflect how differences in project goals,
intentions of investors, climate change and greenhouse gas (GHG) objectives, as well as
energy costs impact the understanding of what a ZEB actually is. This is because each of
these concerns is going to mean different things to different people. For example, a
general contractor is going to have a different objective than the Department of Energy
and a designer is going to have a different goal than someone whose main concern is

 

9
 

 

 

reducing emissions. Thus, Torcellini et al. (2006) presents four different definitions of
ZEBs. A site ZEB produces as least as much energy as it uses in a year, when accounted
for at the site. A source ZEB produces as least as much energy as it uses in a year when
accounted for at the source. Source energy refers to the primary energy used to generate
and deliver the energy to the site. In a cost ZEB, the amount of money the utility pays the
building owner for the energy the building exports to the grid is at least equal to the
amount the owner pays the utility for the energy services and energy used over the year.
A net zero-emissions building produces GHG (greenhouse gas) emissions-free energy in
an amount that is at least as much as it uses from emissions-producing energy sources.
Each one has its own unique advantages and disadvantages. What they all share,
however, is the idea that energy efficiency is the first priority and once that is achieved,
the addition of renewable energy sources can be added to reach the zero balance. Each of
the definitions assumes that they will use the grid for net metering.
The site ZEB produces as much energy as it consumes when accounted for at the
site (Torcellini et al. 2006). Like the others, it can generate energy through a variety of
renewables suitable to the given location. This could be roof-mounted PV, a small-scale
wind turbine, low-imapct hydroelectricity etc. To better guide in the selection of different
supply-side technologies Torcellini et al. (2006) provide a ranking of renewable energy
sources based on minimizing environmental impact through energy-efficient designs and
reducing transportation and conversion losses. Additionally, whether they will be
available over the buildings lifetime and whether they show high replicable potential for
future ZEBs were also taken into account.


 

10
 

 

 

Regardless of type of renewable, the first option is always to reduce the site
energy through low-energy building technologies. This is usually a given but can be
easily overlooked. After this, the best option is to use renewable energy sources available
within the building’s footprint e.g., using PV, solar hot water, and wind located on the
building. Ideally, this is the best option after all efficiency measures have been met. This
is primarily due to the renewables not requiring additional resources, but instead taking
advantage of available space, such as the roof, in cases of PV and wind generation. Next
is the use of renewables from energy sources at the site. These could be PV, solar hot
water, low-impact Hydro, and wind that are on site but not on the building. While still a
stellar option, there may be additional environmental impacts when dealing with sources
away from the building. The last two options are to utilize renewable energy from off-site
sources. For example, one could bring in biomass, ethanol, and biodiesel from another
site or waste stream and process it on site to generate electricity. Lastly, once could
purchase off-site renewables, for example, by buying utility-based wind, PV, emissions
credits, or even hydroelectric energy. However, in the last two cases, one could
potentially purchase all power from hydroelectric or biomass and declare their home
“zero energy,” which is not quite what a ZEH is attempting to reach. Rather it would be
best practice to utilize as much of the first options as possible and only consider the offsite renewables as a last resort, to reach Zero Energy. Figure 1 is representative of the
different renewable energy supply options as discussed above.


 

11
 

 

 

Figure 1. Overview of possible renewable supply options (Marszal et al. 2010)

All four definitions have different goals in mind, each with their own strengths
and weaknesses. One limitation of a site ZEB is that the differing values of various fuels
at the source are not considered. This is because the building site energy is typically
measured at the utility meters and is the total of the electrical, gas, and other types of
energies delivered to the home. In this case, one unit of electricity is equivalent to one
unit of natural gas, despite electricity being 3 times as valuable at the source (Torcellini et
al. 2006). Site energy can be useful in understanding the overall performance of a home,
but it does not take into account the whole story of environmental impacts resulting from
the home’s energy use and thus should generally not be used as a metric to compare

 

12
 

 

 

homes with different mixes of energy types e.g., homes with on-site PV generation. For
example, whether a home is using a site or source ZEB definition will determine the
amount of on-site electricity needed to offset gas use. In the case of a site ZEB, this
would need to be on a 1 to 1 basis and result in a larger PV system than a source ZEB
would require. This is because a site ZEB does not take into account the differences in
energy sources, such as transportation costs; it only compares energy used at the site.
This definition also favors electric equipment, since under this definition; it is more
efficient at the site than its gas counterpart. For example, an electric heat pump would be
favored over natural gas furnaces despite cases where a natural gas furnace may be more
suitable e.g., very cold climates. Nevertheless, a site ZEB is easily verified through
measurements on-site, which makes it an easily repeatable and consistent definition. In
terms of meeting a ZEB policy goal, this definition might be something to consider.
On the other hand, a source ZEB produces as much energy as it consumes as
measured at the source (Torcellini et al. 2006). In order to calculate the building’s total
source energy, the imported and exported energy need to be multiplied by an appropriate
site-to-source energy factor. The NREL used a life cycle assessment to determine
national electricity and natural gas site-to-source energy factors of 3.37 and 1.12 (Deru
and Torcellini 2006). Thus, site gas energy use will have to be offset by onsite electricity
generation on a 3.37 to 1 ratio for source ZEBs. This means that for every 3.37 units of
gas used at the site, 1 unit of electricity must be exported to offset it. In most cases, the
national average site-to-source energy factors are used so that projects can be consistently
compared across the nation. However, this definition has the potential to encourage the
use of gas in as many end uses as possible in order to reach the net zero-energy goal. For

 

13
 

 

 

example, gas could be used to power gas boilers, domestic hot water heaters, or dryers.
This kind of fuel switching and source accounting is one currently economically feasible
way to reach net zero-energy. That is, the higher the total energy use at the site that is
natural gas, the smaller the PV system has to be, thus lowering costs. While natural gas
can’t power everything and it is still a fossil fuel, it is relatively cheap and clean in terms
of non-renewables.
Another potential weakness of this definition has to do with how the site-tosource energy factors were calculated. If we use national averages, this might not reflect
regional differences in electricity generation. For example, here in the Pacific Northwest,
hydropower is a significant portion of our energy portfolio and thus the site-to-source
multiplier is somewhat lower than the national average. Deru and Torcellini (2006)
provide multipliers for three primary grid interconnects and for each individual state.
An additional issue with this definition occurs when gas from fossil fuels is used
to generate electricity on site. Since nearly all ZEB definitions state that a building must
use renewable energy to offset its energy use and reach the ZEB goal, any electricity
generated from fossil fuels cannot be exported and counted towards reaching net zero.
However, taking into account the most cost-optimal methods, this scenario is unlikely to
play out given that buildings will usually need more electricity than they do heat.
However, if energy costs go unmanaged, despite reaching site or source net zero, then a
building may not realize energy cost savings. Thus, cost will likely determine the best
combination of energy efficiency, co-generation, and renewable energy generation at the
site.


 

14
 

 

 

With this in mind, the third definition of a ZEB can be understood i.e., the net
zero-energy cost building. A cost ZEB is one that receives as much financial credit for
exported energy as it is charged on the utility bills (Torcellini et al. 2006). Thus, the
credits received for exported electricity will need to offset the charges incurred for
energy, distribution, peak demand, taxes, and metering for both electricity and gas. This
definition provides an even comparison of different fuel uses at the site and thus the
energy availability and competing fuel costs will be the main determinant of optimal
solutions. One issue with this is that as utility rates vary widely and change constantly, a
building with consistent energy use might meet the ZEB goal one year and not the next.
In terms of wide scale implementation, this definition may not be suitable because utility
rates have the potential to change dramatically. Eventually, as energy efficient buildings
and renewable technologies increase, the effects they will have on the utilities service
area must be taken into account. Not only do utilities purchase fuel to generate their
electricity they also pay to maintain the infrastructure and to provide profitability to their
stakeholders. Thus, if or when significant numbers of buildings reach net zero, the utility
may not have the financial resources to maintain the infrastructure and thus would need
to raise the fixed costs and demand charges. This may or may not impact a buildings
goal, but it is an eventuality that will need to be taken into account. So, while this
definition may not be suitable over the long-term, in all practicalities, cost will be the
greatest determining factor for many when deciding whether or not to build a zero-energy
building, especially in the residential sector.
To achieve a cost ZEB, it is necessary to first reach a certain threshold energy
savings. The less energy required by a building, the less renewable energy it has to

 

15
 

 

 

produce and thus, the less costly the home is overall. Since cost ZEB is primarily
interested in balancing the cost of renewable energy exported to the grid with the amount
the owner pays to the utility, the differences in costs are the main determinant in a homes
ability to reach net zero-energy costs. With this comes the need for aggressive demand
management in order to reduce demand to the point at which the renewable energy source
could offset it. In this case, in order to achieve a cost ZEB, it would be necessary to know
when peak demand charges occur and manage energy use around these. Since peak
demand charges cost more, more renewable energy would be needed to offset the higher
rates. Thus, a utility rate that factors energy use and not peak demand charges would be
more favorable.
Additionally, a net-metering agreement that credits excess electricity generation at
avoided generation costs without PV capacity limits would be ideal. Most states that have
net metering laws require utilities to purchase the excess energy back, although with
different stipulations based on location. The avoided generation costs would be a
valuation of the costs associated with the utility not having to generate energy. It could
also be credited back at the full retail rate, which is usually more than the avoided
generation costs. In Washington, the utilities will pay $0.15/kWh for electricity generated
from PV equipment manufactured out of state and $0.54/kWh for solar generated
electricity from equipment manufactured locally. This program known as Washington
State’s 6170 program expires on July 2020 (DSIRE, 2012). With the average retail rate of
electricity in Washington State being $6.66/kWh in 2010, this incentive program could
offer significant incentives for people to build zero-Energy homes as soon as possible
(DOE and EIA 2012). Nevertheless, if demand charges account for a large portion of the

 

16
 

 

 

utility bills, then a cost ZEB can be difficult to achieve. Thus, demand savings, as
described above, becomes very important in order to reduce overall costs and allow for
greater payback.
Lastly, and perhaps the most suitable in terms of reaching climate change
objectives is the net zero emissions building. It produces emissions-free renewable
energy in an amount that is at least as much as the amount of emissions-producing energy
it uses (Torcellini et al. 2006). While it could be argued that there is no such thing as
emissions-free renewable energy technology, this would assume that we are taking into
account the life cycle of the technology. For the purposes of this thesis, we are only
interested in the process of energy generation. While it would be more accurate to include
life cycle cost analysis, it is beyond the scope of this paper. Thus, renewable energy could
be considered emissions free because it does not release climate-altering elements into
the atmosphere; the central idea with this definition is that the emissions free energy
balances the energy used from conventional sources. Thus, in this way, it reduces its
emissions through using supply side options as mentioned above. Potentially, an allelectric building that gets all its electricity from an off-site zero-emissions source is
already zero-emissions and thus does not have to generate any on-site renewables. This
would be considered an off-site building. However, if the building utilized natural gas, it
would then need to offset this with renewable generation. It could do this by purchasing
enough renewable energy from a hydro utility, for example, to offset this. So, if one lived
in a region with a predominantly renewable energy generation mix, then that ZEB would
need a smaller PV to offset emissions than it would need in a region that used
predominantly coal. However, in both cases, purchasing emissions offsets from other

 

17
 

 

 

sources is considered an offsite ZEB, which is generally not what the net zero-energy
goal entails. Lastly, since utilities often use mixes of energy sources, it could be hard to
calculate the generation source of electricity.
Apart from these definitions, which encompass the main components of what it
means to be zero-energy, other considerations must be taken into account.
For example, the period of time that the building calculation is performed, known as the
period of balance, must be determined (Marszal et al. 2011). This could be the full life
cycle of the building, which would take into account all energy from the moment
construction began. It could also be the operating time of the building (e.g., 100 years or
until demolished), the mortgage period (e.g., 30 years), or most commonly, the annual
balance. The yearly balance is suitable in most cases because it covers all operation
settings with regards to the succession of the seasons. Seasonal or monthly balances have
also been put forth as options. In reviewing several studies, Marszal et al. (2011) found
that the most favored balancing period is the annual balance.
However, the life cycle of a building could be more appropriate because it takes
into account not only the energy use but embodied energy in the building materials,
construction, demolition, and installation (Hernandez and Kenny 2010). This sort of
methodology and type of balance is more in line with evaluating the true environmental
impacts of the building. However, due to the scope of this thesis, we will not be taking
into account life-cycle costs. Nevertheless, this life-cycle analysis does not restrict
calculation of annual energy use to any particular methodology. Instead, any consistent
building energy calculation could be expanded to include a life-cycle perspective. We
would then be considering a life-cycle zero-energy building or LC-ZEB. LC-ZEBs are

 

18
 

 

 

buildings “whose primary energy use in operation plus the energy embedded in building
materials and systems over the life of the building is equal to or less than the energy
produced by renewable energy systems within the building” (Hernandez and Kenny
2010, p. 817).
While life-cycle assessments try to take into account all the energy use
encompassed in the life of the building, many of the publications do not even specify the
type of energy use that is included in their balance (Marszal et al. 2006). These
discrepancies add to the issues that come with having no agreed upon definition of ZEBs
or the type of balance to be used in the calculation methodologies. While the literature
shows the most favored balance being between the energy consumption and the
renewable generation, we noted other definitions above that could be used given the goals
of the project (Marszal et al. 2006). However, even with specified definitions, there are
still other requirements buildings must meet before being constructed. These are energy
efficient requirements, indoor climate requirements and grid-interaction requirements.
We noted that although some definitions do not require energy efficiency before
implementing renewables, it only makes sense that this be the first priority on the path to
net zero. Torcellini et al. (2006, p. 3) give the definition that “a ZEB is a residential or
commercial building with greatly reduced energy needs through efficiency gains such
that the balance of energy needs can be supplied with renewable technologies.” This
provides a stripped down, jargon-free definition of what it ultimately means to be on the
path towards net zero-energy. This thesis will largely be guided by the precepts of this
framework.


 

19
 

 

 

In terms of indoor climate requirements, the literature has been largely quite. Of
course, the comfort of the indoor climate is “always the first priority in building design”
(Sartori et al. 2012, p. 229). Thus, requirements for a good and healthy indoor climate
should be understood and specified. For example, buildings should utilize daylight and
supply sufficient artificial light control, maintain proper atmospheric indoor climate
through temperature and air quality control, and utilize healthy materials with good
acoustics and sound. Marszal et al. (2011) point out that out of the 12 publications
reviewed, only two mentioned indoor climate requirements. Sartori et al. (2012) also only
briefly cover it by pointing out that the climate and comfort standards need to be
accounted for because any variations in the expected outdoor and indoor climates will
affect energy demand (e.g., different temperature settings or hotter/colder years). These
specifications are useful in that they allow one to design a ZEB for a given climate,
which is best because most renewables are climate dependent. However, if ZEBs are
designed properly, most will take this into account regardless of whether or not this is
made explicit.
Lastly, grid interaction requirements are also taken for granted when ZEBs are
being discussed. Most definitions require that the ZEB be connected to the grid without
any details describing the interaction. In most instances, as long as net metering is
available in the location, the perception is that the grid is capable of unlimited energy
storage with no losses. However, this idea is changing with more research investigating
the interaction that would be best for both building and infrastructure (Marszal et al.
2011). The issue lies with the grid-building interaction being hard to define. Since the
approaches depend on which perspective you take (e.g., the grid, the building, or the

 

20
 

 

 

nation), there are going to be different objectives. Two indexes were defined in the
literature to characterize this interaction from the building perspective. One is the load
match index, which describes how much demand is covered by on-site generation or how
much stress is put on the grid. The other is the grid interaction index, which describes the
fluctuation of the energy exchange between the grid and the ZEB. These analyses,
however, require many measurements that may be hard to come by, including the grid
characteristic, location, type and load profile of the building, and time resolution.
Nevertheless, one basic requirement has been identified in the literature i.e., the energy
fed back to the grid has to have the same usability as the energy taken from the grid
(Marszal et al. 2011). This will be assumed to be the case in most instances.
Although the concept of zero-energy buildings is generally inferred, there is still
no agreed upon-definition or standard. Nevertheless, it is now accepted that the
definitions for a ZEH depend on an individual’s objective or the targets that lie behind
the promotion of any zero-energy building. One commonality for all ZEBs, and one that
is used in this thesis is the concept of balancing the weighted demand and supply.
Without the ability to balance the buildings energy consumption with its renewable
energy supply i.e., net-metering, zero-energy buildings may not have reach the potential
that they have today.

Understanding the Current Paradigm
As of May 9 2013, CO2 readings from the Mauna Loa Observatory showed
atmospheric carbon dioxide levels had reached 400 ppmv (parts per million volume)
(Tans and Keeling 2013). This is an increase of 40% relative to preindustrial levels of

 

21
 

 

 

approximately 280 ppmv. These levels have never been seen in human history. This rise
in carbon dioxide has led to observed increases in the global average surface temperature
and ocean temperature as well as widespread melting of snow and ice, resulting in a
rising global average sea level. Thus, there is clear evidence that the warming of the
climate system is unequivocal. Many natural systems around the world are being affected
by regional climate changes, including the ocean, which faces increasing levels of acidity
due an increase in anthropogenic CO2 (IPCC 2007). The Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change (IPCC) reported that “unmitigated climate change would, in the long
run, be likely to exceed the capacity of natural, managed, and human systems to adapt”
(IPCC 2007, p, 65). Thus, it is necessary for us to identify the barriers, limits, and costs
of adaptation and mitigation strategies if we are to take this issue seriously.
The IPCC fourth assessment report found that energy use in buildings offers the
greatest potential for reducing carbon emissions over any other single sector in the US
and abroad (IPCC 2007). Taking this into account, our current housing paradigm is in
great need of a transformation. In understanding the challenges of making this shift,
Farhar and Coban (2008) tease apart some of the misconceptions that they call
“conventional wisdom” from what they term the “new market paradigm.” They
interviewed and sent questionnaires to homebuyers of high performance homes (HPH)
(30-50% savings in utility costs) in the Scripps Highlands development of San Diego as
well as to comparative conventional homeowners. This was the first development in the
U.S. to be built of high performance homes attached to the grid and the first development
to implement net metering. From this study, they identified several misconceptions
associated with HPHs that can also be extended to ZEHs. For example, conventional

 

22
 

 

 

wisdom would lead us to believe that HPHs cost more to build and that only innovators
and early adopters will buy them. It also suggests that homeowners are motivated to
purchase HPHs based on economic payback and that satisfaction with the home is
contingent on this payback. Additionally, given the poor aesthetics of solar panels
affecting home values, production builders should only offer these homes as an option.
However, the results of this study show quite the opposite and suggest what may be a
new market paradigm. For example, they report that production builders can market
HPHs competitively and profitably where subsidies are in place and may even sell them
faster than nearby conventional homes, as was the case with this study. They also note
that buyers of HPHs are the same types of consumers attracted to new production homes
in their price range and that when a homebuyer likes their home’s location, appearance,
and layout, they tend to be unconcerned about the aesthetics of solar features. Lastly,
when it comes to purchasing HPHs, homeowners perceived three major benefits:
altruistic, financial, and personal satisfaction. While the energy saved plays a huge role in
all of these, it is not the determining factor. This study exemplifies some of the main
misunderstandings that we see in terms of the current paradigm and what a possible shift
may look like.
Apart from some of the common misconceptions that we have about consumer
choices on this issue, there is additional research being done in order to understand some
of the barriers perceived by builders. The National Renewable Energy Laboratory, in an
effort to meet the DOE’s ZEH performance goals, is looking into all barriers and has
identified some notable characteristics about builders. In terms of technology, they tend
to avoid those that increase risks, increase overall costs, have potential for customer

 

23
 

 

 

complaints, require additional training and oversight, require new and unfamiliar
materials, require additional planning and codes, and lastly, have the potential to increase
future home warranty or callback costs (Anderson and Roberts 2009). For the most part,
builders are risk-averse in respect to new technologies, however, if they are to continue to
respond to consumer and policy-driven demand, then they are going to need credible
information to decide for themselves whether they can successfully use these new
technologies and products that come with unknown risks and, so far, unproven benefits.
In the United Kingdom, the Code for Sustainable Homes has set a target for all
new homes to be zero-carbon from 2016 on. While technically not referred to as a zeroenergy home, these buildings are expected to produce as much energy as they consume.
With this ambitious target set, there has been an effort to identify some of the challenges
faced by UK builders. Osmani and O’Reilly (2009) conducted a study looking at the
main drivers and barriers from the perspective of builders in the UK. They performed
interviews and sent surveys to the largest homebuilders in England; their results
identified several cultural, financial, and legislative barriers. For example, most
homebuilders revealed a lack of confidence in emerging green technologies, while close
to half of them reported that a lack of widespread customer demand is a significant
barrier. One interviewee pointed out “there is a substantial amount of education that
needs to happen for the general public to appreciate the benefits of zero carbon homes”
(Osmani and O’Reilly 2009, p. 1922) Additionally, homebuilders identified a lack of data
related to the cost of zero-carbon homes and a lack of sales data as financial barriers for
the implementation of ZEHs. Lastly, the definitions of zero-carbon homes as well as too
many government policies (68%) were also perceived as barriers. This study indicates

 

24
 

 

 

that some of the main concerns that builders have are related to a lack of trust in new
technologies as well as a lack of cost data and consumer demand. Since these homes are a
relatively new technology, it seems correct to assume that builders may have a
challenging time leaving the current paradigm behind.
In addition to understanding barriers that UK builders had, Osmani and O’Reilly
(2009) were also interested in influential driving forces that would lead to reaching the
goal of zero-carbon homes. Nearly all builders reported that compliance with
environmental legislation as well as government policies on building practices are key
driving forces to the implementation of zero carbon homes. The overall consensus in the
interviews was that “making zero carbon standards mandatory would be the most
effective way of driving the industry to build zero carbon homes” (p. 1920) While other
drivers were identified, legislative drivers had the highest impact on house builders
current work practices. Although this study was done in England, many of the same
barriers and drivers could apply to U.S. homebuilders. Most significantly, the recognition
that government policy plays a driving role in the development of implementing highly
efficient homes is important to consider. As we reach a point where research and
development are making zero-energy homes a viable option to combat climate change,
the current paradigm may need a nudge in terms of groundbreaking environmental
policy.
On the other hand, what may be applicable in the U.K. might very well be
different in the United Sates. The goal of reaching zero-energy in the building sector is
evident in many developed nations around the world, yet the way in which each country
will transition into this new paradigm may be dependent on the culture itself. An example

 

25
 

 

 

of how cultures influence building practices is presented by Koch et al. (2010) in a study
that compares Swiss building practices to that of the U.S. The study was framed within
the context of moving towards zero-energy homes. They report that Swiss home building
standards are more similar to the commercial standards than the residential standards in
the U.S. In Switzerland, it is common practice to use thick masonry brick-type
components that create more thermal mass than it is to use the U.S. style wood frame.
They also pay significant attention to optimizing the building envelope as well as taking
advantage of highly efficient mechanical systems such as air-to-air heat recovery, radiant
slab heating and cooling, and solar domestic hot water, which are common in U.S.
commercial applications. Swiss homes typically cost $600,000 to purchase and people
tend not to purchase new homes, but rather inherit them.
In order to compare these different standards, this study used the U.S. Energy
Star standards and the Swiss Minergie standards, both of which are categorized as the
current “best practices” in each country, thus represent a starting point for zero-energy.
They modeled a home design that was found in both countries using the software tool
RemRate. This tool predicts annual utility costs and provides a Home Energy Rating
Systems (HERS) index based on a reference building built to specifications of the 2006
International Energy Conservation Code. A home meeting the reference building
standards gets a score of 100 while a net zero-energy home receives 0. The lower the
score, the more efficient a home is. In this, study, the U.S. Energy Star home scored 79,
with the standard U.S. home scoring a 98. The Swiss Minergie home scored a 37, while
the standard Swiss home scored 54. Lastly, two hybrids of each type of home, a hybrid
energy star home and a hybrid Minergie home were modeled. They scored a 45 and 69,

 

26
 

 

 

respectively. Thus, the Swiss building practices, both standard and efficient types, were
more successful in reducing overall energy consumption than those of the U.S.
However, energy performance does not provide a complete picture of overall
performance. This is clearly recognized by the fact that we are capable of building highly
efficient buildings without regard to cost, but once cost is taken into account a different
picture may play out. For example, Koch et al. (2010) calculated which home would be
most cost-effective based on cost of construction and annual energy costs. They found
that the standard U.S. home would be the most cost effective until year 13, with lower
construction costs offsetting energy expenditures for these early years. After this, the
hybrid energy star home would be most cost effective until year 43 at which point the
Minergie home becomes cost effective. These calculations indicate that more expensive
energy-efficient homes can become more cost effective if energy prices were to increase,
as may occur in the future. In terms of culture, people in the U.S. tend to move frequently
and thus a less expensive home may be cost-effective because they do not stay long
enough to experience any of the energy saving benefits that occur down the road. On the
other hand, a Swiss home is a once-in-a-lifetime investment therefore it makes sense to
purchase a home that is cost-effective over a longer period of time.
It is important to consider the implications that culture will have on the
implementation of zero-energy buildings. As was shown above, it will likely be a much
smoother transition for those countries that already practice energy-efficiency as a
standard in their construction practices to move towards zero-energy. It may even be less
costly, since the building industry in these countries is already familiar with green
technologies and there is consumer demand to push the market. On the other hand,

 

27
 

 

 

cultures such as the U.S. could face additional barriers, especially when you take into
consideration that the average home in the U.S. is 50% larger than the average home in
all other developed nations. This is also 50% larger than the average homes built 25 years
ago in the U.S., despite average household size decreasing from 3.1 people in 1970 to 2.6
people in 2007 (Gray and Zarnikau, 2011). Additionally, a major incentive for purchasing
a zero-energy home is the expected payback in terms of the annual energy production. If
homeowners cannot justify making that long-term investment, they may opt for less
efficient homes that are more cost-effective in the short run. This may be the case in the
United States given the fact that 50.2% of homeowners had only been in their house 10
years at the least, while 27.6% had been in their homes for 20 years (U.S. Census Bureau,
2007). Thus, it’s necessary to keep in mind barriers that are presented by our current
paradigm and how we may overcome these given the accelerating pace of research and
development into new cost-optimal designs of zero-energy homes.
Lastly, in understanding our current paradigm and how we can make the
transition to zero-energy, further barriers and challenges to implementation need to be
considered. In their book, “Getting to Zero: Green Building and Net Zero-energy homes”
Gray and Zarnikau (2011) identify some additional key barriers. The most obvious and
the one that this thesis will be addressing is the initial cost of the home. It’s generally the
case that the most efficient technologies require premium initial costs and this will be
reflected in the total price of new, zero-energy homes. Additionally, the on-site
renewable technology that is needed to reduce net consumption is presently (and will
remain for some time) more expensive than purchasing power from the utility grid.
Nevertheless, there are many ways in which this barrier can and is being addressed. It

 

28
 

 

 

also remains to be known exactly how much of an increase in cost zero-energy homes
will have compared to a similar conventional home.

Technological Feasibility
With advancements in new building technologies and efficiency gains, zeroenergy homes are no longer a thing of the past. There are many combinations of materials
and technologies that can be used to construct a ZEB, which are usually reflective of the
type of ZEB being built. With many different possible configurations and variables, it is
often hard to know beforehand whether the ZEB being designed will perform in the real
world as expected. Since this is a relatively new concept and not many ZEBs have been
built, it is often argued that the technology hasn’t caught up yet. This is in fact untrue.
While much of the research relies on modeling and simulation software, mainly because
of the high costs of construction, there still exists research on the construction and
monitoring of experimental ZEBs or highly efficient near zero-energy buildings
(NZEBs). The examples of these types of homes are being built and monitored with the
goal of learning the best and most optimal designs. It has been these experimental and
simulated cases that have provided much of the current measured and predicted data.
Thus, it is in this section that a number of these homes and buildings are highlighted in
order to display the capabilities and feasibility of ZEBs.
In terms of large-scale developments, there have been several projects, which are
highlighted in Gray and Zarnikau (2011). “Solutions Oriented Living” development is a
housing development in Austin, Texas designed by the firm KRDB. It is a mixed-income
development with the goal of building homes that generate as much energy as they draw

 

29
 

 

 

from the grid. The main technologies that allow for this are passive ventilation and day
lighting, thermally efficient windows, structurally insulated panels for the framing
system, modular construction, geothermal heating and cooling, and of course, PV panels.
Also in Texas, “Discovery at Springs Trails” claims to be “Houston’s first solar powered
hybrid community”(Gray and Zarnikau 2011, p. 247). This project utilizes whole house
energy efficiencies and solar power to guarantee that energy bills will be lower than
comparable energy star homes. Some homes are even equipped with battery storage
capable of discharging for several hours at 2 kW. The first homes in the development will
be equipped with GE energy monitoring dashboards to monitor their energy and water
use. In Boulder, Colorado, “ Solar Village Homes” are near zero homes that utilize
passive solar design, Icynene foam insulation, fiberglass windows, solar hot water, and
have PV panels on the roof. Based on modeling, the design team estimates that these
condominiums will save 67,400 kWh a year of electricity. In Chicago, the EcoPower
Project designed zero-energy plans with hopes of creating affordable low-income
housing. To do this they designated the homes as residential solar generation stations in
order to utilize renewable energy credits. They had proposed 100 homes, but only seven
were built. Nevertheless, these achieved 67% energy efficiency, with 33% of that coming
from solar power. Separately, “Premier Gardens” in Sacramento, California, is a 95-home
zero-energy community, which exceeds California’s Title 24 energy cooling
requirements by 50% and utilizes PV, a tankless water heater, mechanically designed
heating and air conditioning, spectrally selective glass windows, and tightly sealed air
ducts. Overall, these homes are expected to save $600 more than the average U.S.
homeowner in energy bills. Lastly, in Germany, the “Solar Settlement” is a housing

 

30
 

 

 

community where all the buildings produce a positive energy balance, thus they are all
net zero. These buildings were built between 2000 and 2005 and use a tenth of the energy
of a conventional house. The extra energy they produce through their PV array is sold
back to the citywide grid.
These examples from Gray and Zarnikau (2011) display that the technology is
here and, in some instances, is being implemented by innovators in production homes.
However, as the examples indicate, those in the United States are working towards netzero, but have yet to make the leap. Effort is being made here in the U.S., but not on the
same scale or as precociously as in places like Germany’s Solar Settlement, However,
this may simply be due to market barriers that have yet to be overcome. The National
Renewable Energy Laboratory identified three levels of market maturity and risk
reduction that it suggest needs to be reached before ZEH technology can be successfully
implemented by builders, contractors, and homeowners (Anderson and Roberts 2008).
First, the technology must meet minimum builder, contractor, and homeowner
performance and reliability requirements. Second, the design, construction, and
commissioning details for integrating the new technology into homes need to be
understood and validated across the board. Lastly, field training, quality
assurance/control, commissioning, and operations/maintenance requirements for the
technology must be integrated into the process of production building. This would ensure
that potential savings and benefits could be achieved once the technologies are broadly
implemented. Whatever barriers remain in the U.S., the fact remains that we can build
and operate homes at net zero-energy.


 

31
 

 

 

Apart from the above examples, several studies have been done all around the
world to determine the feasibility of ZEBs and to measure their actual performance. They
provide invaluable information and at the same time shine light on areas where
information or technology is lacking and areas where we need further research. One study
explores the feasibility of a 110m2, two-bedroom, single-family ZEH in the mild climate
of southern Europe, utilizing solar as its renewable energy source (Carrilho da Graca et
al. 2012). This study used dynamic thermal simulation for two representative house
designs in order to size solar thermal and PV collector systems that would meet the
annual energy needs. They found that the initial increase in cost was between 11% and
22%, with a payback time of 13-18 years. Thus, the study found that, for a southern
European climate, a ZEH is feasible with a moderate increase in initial cost. However,
they also found that the size of the PV system varies by a factor of three depending on the
efficiency of the building and electrical appliances used. This shows how important
efficiency is when it comes to the design process, and this extends to efficient appliances.
Lastly, they calculated a payback taking into account a micro-generation subsidy and
found that it could possibly lead to a faster payback in the range of 8-10 years. In terms
of incentives, subsidies can help considerably for both the builder and homeowner.
Another study was done in the United Kingdom to investigate the feasibility of
ZEH and provide specific design methods to achieve the zero-energy goal (Wang et al.
2009). This study relied on computer simulations of building systems to model zeroenergy house design. EnergyPlus was used to model hourly energy consumption and for
building envelope design while TRANSYS was used for building systems and renewable
energy systems design. They found that it is theoretically possible to achieve ZEH in the

 

32
 

 

 

UK. The annual electricity generated is expected to be 7305.9 kWh, with the energy
consumption being only 6008.9 kWh. The remaining electricity could be used to charge
an electrical vehicle or to sell back to the grid, which, through net metering, is now
becoming widely available. This study, not only showed that is was theoretically
possible; the authors also identified several solutions for U.K. house design that are
particularly suited for that region and that climate. As part of this process, they
recognized three steps that need to be considered: analysis of local climate conditions,
application of passive and advanced designs to minimize load requirements, and the use
of modeling software to investigate various mechanical and renewable energy systems.
In Australia, there has been research conducted from actual measured data from
an off-ground detached family home in southeast Queensland. Miller and Buys (2012),
described their energy goals as the “triple bottom line of sustainability”: economic (selfsufficiency, resilience, adaptability), environmental (passive solar design, low embodied
energy), and social (thermal comfort, universal design). The house easily meets the
annual net energy balance with a total energy consumption of 1.8 MWh and a total
renewable energy electricity generation of 2.77 MWh, thus making this a net-positive
energy home. With Australia’s “Solar Bonus Scheme,” which pays $0.44/kWh of
electricity exported to the grid, the house actually makes money. Rather than paying the
average annual electricity cost of a Queensland resident of $1600, they make a net
income of $829. Considering that the local electric prices have increased nearly 50%
from 2007-2010, this household is relatively unaffected. If it continues in this direction,
the economic benefit of energy efficiency, renewable energy, and ZEHs will grow over
time.

 

33
 

 

 

In the United States, research is also being conducted across the varying climatic
regions. In Las Vegas, a study was conducted looking at the energy and economic
performance of a conventional house versus a ZEH (Zhu et al. 2009). Two identical floor
plans were built side-by-side. One used conventional methods meeting minimum
requirements for building codes, and the other was built utilizing energy efficiency
technologies and solar applications. It was found that four items have a competitive cost
of electricity compared to the commercial rate, i.e., high performance windows, compact
fluorescent lights, air conditioner with water-cooled condenser, and a highly insulated
roof. In the desert climate of Las Vegas, with high solar radiation, the use of high
performance windows is the best for energy savings and it offers a fast payback. Roof
mounted PV tiles allow the ZEH to have a net zero electricity consumption on an annual
basis and with rebates can be more cost-effective. They found that thermal mass walls
would provide better insulation but are too costly to be competitive in the market.
Although they used real houses for their study, they still relied on ENERGY10 and
eQUEST3.6 for simulations of energy utilization. The climate data were also collected at
the site in 2006, but they employed TMY2 data as well.
Separately, but also in Las Vegas, a study was done to simulate the energy
consumption of the heating and cooling loads of two residential homes and compare
these results to actual experimental results (Madeja and Moujaes 2008). Trace700, was
the software used for simulated data. The two homes were identical, except one is a ZEH
with the latest technology and the other a baseline of common construction practices.
During their testing phase, the homes served as model homes, to be unoccupied, but
subject to foot traffic from visitors. The goal of the study was to see whether a widely

 

34
 

 

 

used building load and energy analysis software package could accurately predict the
energy consumption of two constructed homes in heating and cooling. They also looked
at comparing the differences in energy consumption between the two homes. What they
found was that although Trace700 had some over-and-under predictions based on the
day-by-day simulations, it was quite accurate for the entire monitoring period, with a
range or error being between 2% and 11%. While this study was primarily concerned
with comparing the simulated data with real data, it shows that the modeling software
designed to simulate energy performance can be a reliable and useful tool on the path
towards designing ZEHs. Since it is extremely costly to build homes for research
purposes, it is absolutely essential that we have accurate and effective technological
resources, such as these widely used models.
Most of the previous examples have been cases of warmer or mild climates.
However, ZEHs are and can be built in areas where one might not expect. A study done
in Denver, Colorado shows the performance results from a 1280 ft2, three-bedroom ZEH
(Norton and Christensen 2008). This ZEH was the result of collaboration between the
NREL and Habitat for Humanity and was designed using an early version of the BEopt
building optimization software. To exceed the net zero goal, it utilized envelope
efficiency; efficient equipment, appliances, lighting; a PV system; and solar thermal
features to exceed the net zero goal. From April 2006 to March 2007, the home’s 4kW
PV system produced 5127 kWh of electricity and only used 3586 kWh of electricity and
57 therms of natural gas. Overall, it produced 24% more energy than it used. They found
that the most difficult design challenge is sizing a PV system to achieve net zero when
the majority of energy used is dependent on plug loads, which are dependent on occupant

 

35
 

 

 

choices and behavior. Thus, if someone likes to maintain their furnace at 70 F°, rather
than 65 F°, this could have an impact on the net-balance regardless of design. The authors
also note that the economics of excess annual PV production is dependent on net
metering agreements and thus ZEHs will be more cost-effective in areas where utilities
offer reimbursements for exported electricity.
Net zero-energy homes are also being built in Massachusetts, by a production
builder who has been building them since 2008 (Bergey and Uneo 2011). The builder is
currently working on multiple, small-scale subdivisions of 20 or more houses, utilizing
solar, super-insulated, double-stud above grade walls, triple-glazed, low-emissivity
krypton-filled windows; and very high airtightness. The homes range from 1100 to 2600
ft2, with one to two stories, and all have roof-mounted PV systems. In terms of fuel
selection, they utilize solar and natural gas. Based on the Building America Benchmark
assumptions of hot water and appliance use, using gas saves more than $350 a year
relative to electric heating. Two-thirds of this savings is in water heating, with the other
third being split between cooking and clothes drying. This large energy and costs savings,
due to avoiding electric heating, often supports installing gas appliances wherever
feasible. However, it is noted that some designers have preferred to steer away from gas
combustion appliances, believing that their present advantage in reaching net zero will
eventually fade away as grid electricity is increasingly produced by renewables. While
this could eventually occur, as of now, natural gas has provided a stepping-stone for costeffective zero-energy homes.
As is seen in the above examples, these homes are being built using today’s
technology. Some are being built for the purpose of research, while others are being built

 

36
 

 

 

by innovative green builders. In both cases, it is clear that we are beyond questions of
technological feasibility; what remains to be investigated lies within the realm of costeffectiveness. Now that we have the technology and it can meet our goals, we need to
figure out the least-costly way to implement these technologies. It may be some years
before we see net zero-energy homes being built on a production scale, but it will not be
because of a lack of available technology. Perhaps the biggest challenge to overcome is
how to make widely available the information and tools that are already out there.
In the United States, the Department of Energy is the federal agency heading
much of the research in this area, with its Building America Program, whose goal is to
demonstrate how cost-effective strategies can reduce home energy use by up to 50% for
both new and existing homes, in all climate regions by 2017 (Bianchi 2011). As part of
this process, the DOE have developed the Building America House Simulation Protocols,
which are aimed at assisting researchers in tracking the progress of multi-year energy
reduction against specific research goals for new and existing homes. These protocols
come preloaded in the Building Energy Optimization (BEopt) software tool, developed
by the NREL to help create market-ready energy solutions that improve the efficiency of
homes on the path towards net zero. This specialized computer program is designed to
identify the most optimally efficient designs at the lowest possible cost. It is technologies
like this that will become invaluable in helping the building industry become aware of
how to build zero-energy homes cost-effectively. Without being able to accurately predict
how much a ZEH will cost and how it will perform, the risk associated with ZEHs may
be too high for the building industry to consider.


 

37
 

 

 

In sum, the literature on zero-energy homes is still lacking in key areas. This
becomes clear after taking into account the literature as a whole. There is a general
consensus as to what a “zero-energy home” would require depending on ones objective.
There are also several working definitions with more likely yet to come. From the
literature, one get’s a sense that we have grasped the technology and can build zero
energy homes relatively easily. However, what is lacking is the need for more data and
information, particularly on the sides of the consumer and producer, i.e., the homebuyer
and homebuilder. They need to know what it is going to cost to build and operate this
new breed of homes. At what cost can the homebuilders build an energy-efficient home,
and what information do they need to provide the homebuyer to make them understand
the increase in costs due to energy efficiency measures. Oftentimes, a homebuilder just
complies with new building codes, generally increasing energy efficiency, but with no
regard for the homeowner’s awareness. Perhaps, homebuyers would be interested in
purchasing an energy-efficient home if there were options in their price range. It is
obvious that these homes will cost more initially, but they do provide a return on
investment in terms of money that homeowners will save on lower energy bills, and
create an avenue in which we can reduce the carbon footprint of our built environments.
As we surpass a global atmospheric carbon dioxide concentration of 400 ppmv, it is
becoming increasingly more apparent that a paradigm shift is needed in the building
industry. Apart from climate change, however, is the inevitability of rising energy prices.
If energy prices rise, as they are expected to, these homes will become more costeffective the further we move into the future, as well as provide security from unforeseen
energy crises. In terms of the homeowner, there are clear incentives for purchasing an

 

38
 

 

 

energy-efficient home. For the homebuilder, there is room for profit as in any business.
They just require the assurance and the cold hard numbers that an investment in this
arena will not disappoint. In terms of our government, whose role it is to guide our
country’s direction, there is an urgency to pass measures that directly address climate
change. What better way than to begin with an industry that has a thirst for energy. In
determining the cost-effectiveness of ZEHs in Washington, this thesis is attempting to
identify, for a given climate, where we stand in terms of incentivizing these homes to
both sides of the market. We can build the homes; we now need to know if we can afford
them.

 


 

39
 

 

 

Methods

The objective of this research project is to determine the cost-effectiveness of net
zero-energy homes and near net zero-energy homes for several locations throughout
Washington State. In doing so, it was necessary to develop house designs that integrated
energy-efficiency and on-site renewable PV generation that could be successfully used on
a production basis. The house designs are location-specific and meant to achieve whole
house energy savings for the varying levels of energy efficiency on the path to net zero.
In order for these types of innovative building energy technologies to compete viably
with conventional homes, it is necessary that they be demonstrated to cost-effectively
increase overall product value and quality while at the same time reducing energy use
significantly. The research approach taken includes the use of the Building Energy
Optimization (BEopt) software to provide cost and performance data for individual house
designs. BEopt utilizes a sequential search technique that measures system performance
and cost trade-offs as they relate to the whole building energy performance and cost
optimization. This includes interactions between advanced envelope designs, mechanical
and electrical systems, lighting systems, appliances, plug loads, energy control systems,
renewable energy systems, and on-site power generation.
All energy savings in this thesis are defined in terms of source energy, or primary
energy, as discussed earlier in the literature review, rather than site energy. This allows
for the use of a source-to-site energy ratio, which determines the percentage of source
energy that is saved. The energy efficiency measures that BEopt evaluates save more
energy than just the amount saved at the site. This is sometimes referred to as

 

40
 

 

 

“downstream efficiency.” For example, if the source-to-site ratio is 3:1, then one unit of
energy saved at the site will save three units of source energy. Thus, when PV is added to
the home, one unit of electricity produced could offset three units of source energy that
doesn’t have to be produced from other sources (e.g., natural gas). In order to assess the
relative efficiencies of buildings with varying proportions of site and source energy
consumption, it’s necessary to convert these two types of energy into equivalent units of
raw fuel consumed to generate the one unit of energy consumed at the site.
In analyzing the least-cost path to homes that produce at least as much energy as
they use annually, we begin with a base case, which is often a current practice building or
code-compliant building. This ensures a well-defined reference for the evaluation of
energy saving goals. The chosen base case or reference building for this project is the
Building America (BA) B10 Benchmark, which was developed by the DOE and NREL
(Hendron and Engebrecht 2010). The B10 benchmark, referred to as the Benchmark for
this project, is consistent with the 2009 International Energy Conservation Code (IECC).
The Benchmark represents typical construction at a fixed point in time so it can be used
as the basis for multi-year energy savings goals without the complications of chasing a
moving target. A series of user profiles that represent the behavior of a typical set of
occupants is used in conjunction with the Benchmark, providing a standard set of
occupant behavior as well. Since BEopt, the tool utilized in this thesis, has been
specifically developed and tailored to meet Building America’s needs, it is the simulation
tool recommended for this type of systems analysis. Thus, for each analysis in this
project, the reference building will be the BA Benchmark. Given that this research is
attempting to compare the cost-effectiveness of ZEHs to a typical conventional home

 

41
 

 

 

with average energy use profiles, the BA Benchmark seemed appropriate. This is because
of the significant research and effort that went into developing a national base case based
on the IECC, the primary residential model energy code used in the U.S. Thus, it
represents the current standard of energy efficiency in the residential building sector. This
works for research in Washington State because it maintains a statewide building code
program and has a history of adopting the latest energy codes. In turn, most current
conventional homes in Washington have to be built to the IECC standard. To see a
complete list of B10 Benchmark Specifications, see the Building America House
Simulation Protocols (Hendron and Engebrecht 2010). It is not included here for the sake
of space.
In order to evaluate the cost required to reach a specific energy target in BEopt,
the energy and cost results can be plotted in terms of annual costs (the sum of utility bills
and mortgage payments for different energy options) versus the percent energy savings as
shown in Figure 2. The optimal least-cost path can then be determined by connecting the
points for building designs that achieve varying levels of energy savings at minimal cost
i.e., the cost that establishes the lower bound of results from all possible building designs
for a given location. While this type of building energy simulation is often used for trial
and error and “what-if” options of building designs, the applications do not stop there.
This project uses BEopt in order to generate cost data for a Benchmark building on the
path towards zero-energy for several locations throughout Washington. While not
intending to build the designs, the software provided cost data for designs that would
otherwise be difficult or near impossible to determine.


 

42
 

 

 

For each location, BEopt identifies the design with the minimum annual cost that
balances investments in efficiency versus utility bill savings. This point could be
identified in purely economic terms as the most cost-optimal design; however, there are
often other energy savings targets that are important as well. In this case, the focus is on
designs that achieve varying levels of energy savings on the path to zero-energy. The
method used by BEopt does not currently include models to evaluate the impacts of nonenergy market drivers such as durability, reliability, ease of install, local supply
availability, warranty callbacks etc. Thus, the data provided is limited to determining the
minimum requirement based on marginal cost and energy performance for a given
design. An example of the least-cost optimization results are given in Figure 2 (Hendron
and Engebrecht 2010).

Figure 2. Sample results showing all points in neighborhood of least-cost curve

 

43
 

 

 

In the above example, each symbol represents a particular simulation in the optimization
search, with different iterations represented by different colors. This allows the user to
pick through the results one iteration at a time to see how the optimization progressed. It
should be noted that the points on the least-cost curve represent potential performance
that can be achieved by homes that are fully optimized in terms of energy cost
performance and should not be used as a predictor.

BEopt and Modeling Cost Optimal Designs
In order to deliver zero-energy homes, the barriers between building design,
performance, and cost-effectiveness need to be overcome. One of the most effective ways
of doing this is through the use of building performance simulation tools (BPS), such as
BEopt. Since there are so many options to reduce energy in buildings, it can be difficult
to determine which are the most appropriate technologies to implement and/or which are
the most cost-effective. Even with the proper tools, designing a ZEH can be a complex,
costly, and tedious task with a high level of uncertainty that comes with not knowing the
occupant’s energy use, for example, or even how climate change will play out. Despite
these uncertainties, all sorts of tools are currently available and each offer different
capabilities depending on whether they are design oriented (HEED, e-Quest, ENERGY10, Vasari, Solar Shoebox, Open Studio Plug-in, IES-VE-Ware, Design Builder,
ECOTECT etc.) optimization oriented (Opt Plus, Genet, DER-CAM, Homer, BEopt etc.)
or a bit of both (Brown et al 2010, Attia and De Herde 2011). Depending on ones
motivations or purpose, there likely exists a tool that is capable of helping reach it. With
the design goal of zero-energy buildings being mostly performance based, the energy

 

44
 

 

 

performance goals must be taken into account early in the design process. This is where
these tools can offer the greatest support particularly since 20% of the design decisions
made early on will influence 80% of the rest of the design (Attia et al. 2012). Thus, being
able to predict or model different designs using software tools is absolutely fundamental.
While much work is being done to create more useful tools, particularly in the early
architectural design phase, the existing tools can be very useful depending on ones
purpose.
If an individual is primarily concerned with optimization, that is, a ZEH that is
both energy-efficient and cost-effective, then a tool such as BEopt might be the most
suitable. There exist other tools that are capable of similar simulation results, however,
BEopt is unique in that a major component of it focuses on cost-optimal designs. Thus, if
cost is a major motivation for the designer, then BEopt, the freeware developed by the
NREL with funding from the DOE, may be the best tool, especially since it is readily
available and user friendly. Widely used as part of the Building America Program, BEopt
uses the simulation software DOE2 and TRNSYS or EnergyPlus to determine the optimal
energy use of a given building design and TMY2/TMY3 for weather data. It provides a
consistent method for comparing costs, energy savings, and interactions between large
numbers of different combinations of energy saving options that can potentially be used
to achieve whole-building energy savings on the path to reaching net zero.
In terms of meeting specific energy-efficiency targets, BEopt is particularly
helpful. Since it plots points along the path to net zero, one can determine the percentage
of whole building energy savings that corresponds to a reduction in their annual energy
costs. Such a plot also shows the incremental increase in costs associated with increase in

 

45
 

 

 

percent energy savings. Figure 3, from Christensen et al. (2006) shows this conceptually.
The X-axis represents the percent energy savings that a home could potentially achieve
on the path to net zero, 100% being the achievement of net zero. The Y-axis represents
the annualized mortgage payments plus the utilities, which for the purposes of this thesis,
refers to only those utilities related to energy e.g., electric and natural gas. The green
curve, or cash flow, is the total annual cost of both mortgage and utilities at each level of
energy savings. The blue downward sloping curve represents the utility bill costs as a
function of energy efficiency. Thus, this graph is essentially showing what happens with
increased energy efficiency, particularly for those homes on the path to net zero.

Figure 3. Conceptual plot of the least-cost path to a ZEH


 

46
 

 

 

Point 1, on the graph, represents the reference building. That is, a building that is a user
defined base case or a climate specific Building America Benchmark building that is
generated by the BEopt software. Often times, the reference building will be a
conventional home built to the current building codes for that region. Point 2 represents
the least-cost point on the path towards zero-energy. Here, one is able to achieve a lower
annual cost compared to the reference building by making efficiency gains that result in
lower energy bills. The increase in cost, due to beyond code changes is reflected in a
higher mortgage payment, but still results in a lower cost than the reference. Point 3
represents higher energy savings; lower utility bills, but a slightly higher mortgage than
points 1 and 2. This point results from implementing additional efficiency gains from
point 2 until the marginal cost of energy savings equals the cost of producing PV energy
at point 3. After point 3, there is a constant increase in “cash flow”, or combined utility
and mortgage, until a home reaches net zero. This is because, after point 3, it is just a
matter of adding additional PV or renewable energy generation until zero-energy is
achieved at point 4. Thus, the additional increase in cost due to achieving additional
energy savings becomes reflected in a higher cash flow, although corresponding with a
constant decrease in utility bills. When the net zero point is reached, the home no longer
has any utility bills but is subject to the highest mortgage rate of all. What is not
represented in this graph is the cost-savings over the life of the home, which, if total
utility savings are taken into account, could result in a home of comparable costeffectiveness to that at point 1. The difference would be that instead of paying utility bills
every year, the owner would pay a higher mortgage that incorporates the initial increase
in costs, but would enjoy a partial return on that investment in the form of energy

 

47
 

 

 

savings. One could also think of it as paying the utility bills 30 years in advance. There
are additional benefits, other than costs, such as reduction in green house gases, but these
can be difficult to quantify. Nevertheless, if these benefits could be quantified or if a
carbon tax were to be implemented, then one could realize a faster return on investment
than they would through energy savings alone. Figure 3 essentially represents what the
BEopt software is capable of doing by determining building energy optimization for
every possible point along the curve.
There are two types of energy optimization - global and constrained (Christensen
et al. 2006). If the goal were purely economics, then energy optimization would be about
finding the global optimum. This is the minimum annual cost that balances investments
in energy efficiency with utility bill savings (point 2 in Figure 3). On the other hand,
there can be reasons other than economics to target a specific energy savings goal. With a
target in mind (e.g., 50% efficiency) economic optimization can be used to determine the
optimal design to achieve this target. This type of constrained optimization can be used
for any target on the path to zero-energy and, in terms of policy, could help establish
what an optimal path would look like. It is also advantageous for the optimization process
to include multiple solutions for optimal and near-optimal designs. Near-optimal designs
achieve the zero-energy goal or another level of energy savings with the total costs close
to, but not at, the optimal design total cost. Given the uncertainties that are embedded in
cost assumptions and energy use predictions, near-optimal points could be as good as
optimal points, in terms of being within a similar range. These designs are identified in
BEopt and could be used for a variety of non-energy and cost reasons.


 

48
 

 

 

Although BEopt’s design purpose was to find optimal building designs along the
path to zero-energy, it is also meant to accelerate the process of developing these highperformance building designs in an effort to move towards a cleaner and more
sustainable future. As we tackle this challenge, more advanced tools will be needed and
BEopt happens to be one of these. Figure 4 provides a basic diagram of how the BEopt
software utilizes established and well-known simulation engines such as TRNSYS and
DOE2 (Christensen et al. 2006). For example, TMY2 weather data are needed for each
given location, which are then used by TRNSYS to run simulations for PV generation
based on the inputs in BEopt. DOE2 is used in a similar way, but uses the weather data to
generate heating, cooling, lighting and appliance requirements based on BEopt inputs. All
together, they can systematically provide optimal zero-energy home designs.

Figure 4. Optimization with multiple simulation programs

The software includes a main input screen that allows the user to select, from
many predefined options (Building geometry, PV system parameters, economic
parameters, and energy savings options), which are then used in the optimization. The

 
49
 

 

 

options are intended to represent readily available products and construction techniques
and have a first cost and lifetime cost associated with them. Costs are retail and include
national average estimated costs for hardware, installation labor, overhead, and profit.
The lifetime for building construction options is assumed to be 30 years but, as with
everything, this can be user defined (Christensen et al. 2006). It also includes an output
screen that allows users to display their results for many optimal and near optimal
designs. Lastly, it includes an options library spreadsheet, where the user can review and
modify the information on all available options, such as cost assumptions, etc.
Utilizing the above simulation engines, BEopt automates the process of
identifying optimal designs, using a sequential search technique. At each step along the
path, BEopt runs a series of simulations incorporating every user-selected option, one at a
time, and searches for the most cost-effective combination of options. This technique has
several advantages. First, it is able to find the intermediate optimal points along the path.
These are the minimum-cost designs for different energy savings targets and not just the
global optimum. It also utilizes discrete, rather than continuous, building options, thus
providing realistic construction choices. Lastly, it is able to provide multiple near-optimal
designs that are identified at each energy-savings level, which provide alternate designs
close to the optimal. BEopt is also capable of up to 20 user-defined cases in a single
project file. These can be used to analyze building performance as a function of climate
and thus location. Cases could also be used to study how building performance is affected
by different economic parameters, such as fuel costs. Multiple cases are also useful in
determining PV systems for a given design, different heating, windows, or any options
selected for optimization.

 

50
 

 

 

There are several published reviews of the BEopt software with it being regarded
as having a high accuracy rate because of its reliable and well-known simulation engines
as well as its sequential search technique. (Attia and De Herde 2011). Attia and De Herde
(2011) analyzed several simulation tools and rated them according to their Intelligence,
Interoperability, process adaptability, and accuracy. BEopt had a low rating for
interoperability, because it has its own built-in-3-D modeler, without any exchange with
CAD, gbXML, BIM, or other drawing tools. This limits it to certain building geometries,
but as a tool for residential homes, this limitation may not be a big concern for most
users. They rated BEopt as having medium intelligence and usability as well as a high
process adaptability. Intelligence mainly refers to its function capacity while process
adaptability is the ability to support different levels of data. A separate study also
analyzed several tools for optimization and found that BEopt is currently the most
effective tool, in terms of achieving quick optimization for both efficiency measures and
different renewable alternatives for various building types (Brown et al. 2010). The
hurdles BEopt faces are that it is used solely for residential buildings and utilizes only
solar applications as its renewable energy source.
Lastly, BEopt was mentioned in a report by the Federation of American Scientists
on the “America Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009” (Talapatra 2009). This bill, also
known as the Waxman-Markey Bill, did not pass, but had the goal of achieving 30%
reduction in energy use in new buildings compared to the IECC 2006 baseline code by
2010. It also targeted 50% by 2014, and 5% for every additional three years following,
with an end goal of net zero-energy. The report mentions BEopt as a critical tool that
could help developers meet targets such as these. The paper even suggests a portable

 

51
 

 

 

BEopt application that could have been used by building inspectors to examine the costeffectiveness of making specific changes to a building’s design had these codes been
passed. While the Waxman-Markey Bill did not pass, these targets will eventually be set
and BEopts potential will likely be realized.

BEopt Inputs
BEopts method of analysis is capable of including any system option or
component whose performance can be defined in the context of EnergyPlus or DOE2 and
TRNSYS and for which first costs, installation costs, operation and maintenance costs,
and replacement costs can be specified over a 30 year life span. For this project, Energy
Plus was used as an alternative to the DOE2 and TRNSYS simulation engines, for the
simple reason that it required only one additional piece of software. As is the case in any
analysis, the results are subject to the assumptions used during this project. For the
purpose of evaluating the cost performance tradeoffs for different energy performance
targets, costs and performance for a range of currently available production building
materials and components were used.
The same building characteristics were used for each location throughout
Washington State. It was a simple two-story, 2496 ft2 residential building with an
attached two-car garage (see Figure 5).


 

52
 

 

 

Figure 5. Graphical representation of the modeled ZEH
The building was modeled with a foundation typical of the Washington climate; slab on
grade for the attached garage and a four-foot ventilated crawlspace for the rest of the
living area. The building has two-foot eaves. Window area is assumed to be 15% of floor
area and is distributed with 20% on the front and sides and 40% on the back of the house.
Adjacent buildings, 15 feet to the north and south provide shading of sidewalls. This
study was limited to an Eastern orientation for each location (i.e., the compass direction
of the front door). Other orientations may have an impact, however, they were not
considered due to modeling time constraints. The heating set point was set at 71 degrees
F, while cooling set point was set to 76 degrees F. Humidity was constant at 60%. These
are the Benchmark heating and cooling comfort requirements that were assumed to model
each home on the path to net-zero.
The energy options considered in this study include space-conditioning systems
(up to SEER 24.5 i.e., seasonal energy efficiency ratio), envelope systems, hot water
systems, lighting systems, major appliances, and residential PV up to 8 kW (see Figure
6). No options that contribute to miscellaneous electric loads other than major appliances

 

53
 

 

 

were included. This is allows the same usage for all homes. The homeowner’s costs
calculated for this project assumed a 30 year mortgage at 7% interest rate with a 3%
general inflation rate and 3% discount rate. No maintenance costs were used in this study
assuming all inputs have a lifetime of 30 year. The occupancy and operational
assumptions are defined in the Building America Benchmark and include time-of-day
profiles for occupancy, appliance and plug loads, lighting, domestic hot water use, and
ventilation. All results are calculated relative to a base case or reference building for each
location. This reference building, known here as the Benchmark, defines wall, ceiling,
and foundation insulation levels as well as framing factors, window areas, U-factors and
solar heat gain factors, interior shading, overhangs, air infiltration rates, duct
characteristics, and heating, cooling, and hot water system efficiencies. The Benchmark
represents standard building practices for the given location.


 

54
 

 

 

Figure 6. BEopt input selection screenshot

Each option has an assumed initial cost and lifetime cost. Costs are retail and
include national average estimated costs for hardware, installation labor, overhead, and
profit. Some costs are input as unit costs that are multiplied by a category constant. For

 

55
 

 

 

example, ceiling insulation cost is an input measured per square foot and automatically
multiplied by ceiling area. Other cost inputs are energy option specific such as the cost of
solar water heating systems. Additional inputs are based on total costs e.g. the cost of
wall construction with different insulation values. This can be done because BEopt will
calculate the difference between the option costs. Construction costs are based on average
national cost data. Windows and HVAC systems are based on quotes from the
manufacturer’s suggested retail price. All building construction options are assumed to
have a 30-year lifetime, which is the typical span of a mortgage. Equipment and
appliance options typically have a 10 to 15 year lifetime and lighting options are based on
the cumulative hours of use.
Utility costs are assumed to escalate at the rate of inflation, so they are constant in
real terms. The mortgage interest rate is 4% above the rate of inflation. The on-site power
option used was a residential PV system, up to 8 KW, with installed cost of $5.50 per
peak wattDC, including value of operation and maintenance costs. This cost is
independent of PV system size. Additional costs that might be associated with mounting
large PV systems were not taken into account. Natural gas is assumed to cost
$1.19/therm, which is taken from the state average. Electricity costs were also taken from
state average and are $0.07/kWh. The cost data was based on the latest EIA data, which
BEopt updates with each new release. The costs estimates used from BEopt do not
include the initial costs required to reengineer home designs, state and local financial
incentives and rebates, or hidden costs, such as warranty and call back costs that are not
accounted for as part of the operational and maintenance costs.


 

56
 

 

 

In order to provide an assessment of the differences between location and weather
patterns throughout Washington State, system optimizations were run for nine locations Seattle, Bellingham, Fort Lewis, Olympia, Whidbey Island, Spokane, Yakima, Port
Angeles, and Walla Walla. Locations were chosen from a list of available TMY3 weather
data for Washington State with an emphasis on choosing a variety of localities from
every corner of Washington (Figure 7).

-120°

'
­
Legend
Cities

"

'
­ Bellingham
_ Fort Lewis
^
F Whidbey Island
G
D Olympia
" Port Angeles
j Seattle
k
? Spokane
#
0 Walla Walla
!
. Yakima

F
G
j
k
_
D ^
_
^

WASHINGTON

?
!
.

Interstate Highways
Rivers
Lakes
State Boundaries

IDAHO

#
0

OREGON

_
^
-120°

Locations for modelled zero-energy
homes in Washington state

0

12.5

25

50

75

100
Miles

Albers Projection
Central Meridian: -96
1st Std Parallel: 20
2nd Std Parallel: 60
Latitude of Origin: 40

Created by Floyd Beaman

Figure 7. Locations for modeled zero-energy homes in Washington State

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis and Return on Investment
Cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) refers to the evaluation of specific alternative
interventions in which costs and consequences are taken into account in a systematic

 

57
 

 

 

way. It is most often used as a decision-oriented tool, in that it is designed to ascertain
which particular intervention will be the most cost-effective, i.e., the most economical
based on the tangible benefits produced by money spent. For example, there are many
alternative approaches for pursuing such goals as production-scale net zero-energy homes
or even a minimum level of home energy-efficiency. These could include the adoption of
new building codes, new building materials and technologies, educational training,
computer and modeling assistance, and so on. One cost-effective solution to this
challenge is to determine the costs and effects of building zero-energy homes for
alternative locations throughout a given region, in this case, Washington State. In doing
so, we can then determine which alternative shows the greatest impact of achieving a
cost-effective zero-energy home and determine whether any of the alternatives are costeffective compared to doing nothing at all, which is here referred to as the null
alternative. That is, rather than building a zero-energy home, what would the costs and
effects be of building a new, up-to-code, production home compared to that of a ZEH?
Cost-effectiveness analysis is very similar to cost-benefit analysis (CBA) in that
they both represent economic evaluations of alternative resource use and measure costs in
the same way. However, they differ in that CBA is used to address only those types of
alternatives whose outcomes can be measured monetarily. This means that all costs and
benefits are monetized and everything is essentially translated into dollars. However,
CEA focuses on non-monetary outcomes, which is why it is so prevalent in the health
sector where risk reduction, changes in health status, weight loss, etc., are primary goals
that are difficult to monetize. Thus, the difference between CBA and CEA depends
mostly on what is being measured, with CEA looking at the incremental cost per unit of

 

58
 

 

 

effectiveness for each alternative rather than the ratio of benefit to cost and return on
investment.
The purpose of cost-effectiveness analysis is to determine which alternative or
combination of alternatives can achieve a particular objective at the lowest cost. The
underlying assumption is that the different alternatives have different associated costs and
different effects. By choosing those with the least-cost for a given outcome, society can
use its resources more effectively. The resources that are saved through using more costeffective solutions can be devoted to expanding other goals or to other important social
endeavors. In this project, CEA is used to first compare the cost-effectiveness of several
ZEHs throughout Washington to that of the null alternative, which is the Benchmark. In
determining the cost-effectiveness of ZEHs compared to the Benchmark, one can
determine the potential cost-effectiveness of building these homes presently.
Additionally, the alternatives can be compared to each other, in order to determine which
of all the alternatives is the most cost-effective.
There are varying techniques for doing cost-effectiveness analysis, however, the
basic technique has been to derive results for effectiveness of each alternative using
standard evaluation procedures or studies and to combine such information with cost data
that are derived using the ingredients approach. The ingredients approach was developed
to provide a systematic way for evaluators to estimate the costs of social interventions
(Levins and McEwan 2001). The general idea is that every intervention uses ingredients
that have a value or cost. If the ingredients can be identified and their costs can be
ascertained, we can estimate the total costs of the intervention as well as the cost per unit
of effectiveness, benefit, and utility. The ingredients approach goes by other names in the

 

59
 

 

 

literature on cost analysis and may sometimes be referred to as the “resource cost model.”
Nevertheless, both require that each intervention or alternative be exhaustively described
in terms of their ingredients or the resources that are required to produce the outcomes
that will be observed. Thus, all ingredients must be carefully identified for purposes of
placing a value or cost on them. In this particular project, BEopt allows us to choose
which ingredients we would like to use in our simulations as well as the optimal
ingredients for a home on the path to net zero. It also provides us with cost data for each
ingredient or input, such as the costs of different water heating systems or different
HVAC systems. In this regard, BEopt allows one to model designs on the path to zeroenergy and thus identify the ingredients that change along the way as well as the costs. It
is also able to provide effectiveness results in terms of the percentage of energy saved
compared to the benchmark. Thus, we can determine the cost-effectiveness of each
alternative by relating the total cost to that of the effectiveness, or in this case, the percent
of energy saved.
This is done using, what is termed, the cost-effectiveness ratio, which can be
obtained by dividing costs by units of effectiveness:
Cost-Effectiveness Ratio

=

Total Cost
Units of Effectiveness

Units of effectiveness are simply a measure of any quantifiable outcome central to the
objective of the project. For example, in the case of mandating air bags in cars, one could
use the number of lives saved as the unit of effectiveness (Wholey et al. 2010). Using the
formula above we could generate a cost-effectiveness ratio that would give us dollars per
life saved. One could then compare this ratio to the cost-effectiveness ratios of other

 

60
 

 

 

transportation safety policies, to determine the most cost-effectiveness in terms of lives
saved.
It is ordinarily the case that the focus in a CEA is on one primary outcome;
however, CE ratios can be calculated for additional outcomes as well. For instance, in
this project, CE ratios are calculated for nine zero-energy home locations throughout
Washington State, each with 10 outcomes. The objective here is to compare the CE ratios
of building a home along the path to net zero to that of building a conventional or status
quo home i.e. the Benchmark. Thus, CE ratios are also calculated for 10 outcomes,
including the Benchmark. That is, in addition to looking at the cost-effectiveness of
ZEHs (homes with 100% energy savings), this project is also interested in determining
the cost-effectiveness at different points along the path to zero-energy. So, CE ratios are
calculated for each location given designs with outcomes of varying percent of energy
savings. This allows us to compare the cost-effectiveness of different outcomes rather
than just looking at complete ZEHs. These different outcomes of energy saved also serve
as a measure of effectiveness. Since the ultimate objective is to reach 100% energy
savings or net zero, determining the cost per unit of energy saved provides us with a
valuable measure by which we can understand the current cost-effectiveness of ZEHs.
Once the ingredients have been identified and the associated costs and
measurements of effectiveness have been quantified, it is important to discount costs and
obtain present values. It is also important to recognize that by purchasing a home that is
more efficient than the Benchmark, an individual will be spending more money upfront
for the energy-efficient technology. While they will receive a payback in lower energy
bills, they pay more now than they would by purchasing a Benchmark home. Since they

 

61
 

 

 

will not have that money to spend in other ways, an opportunity cost incurs when
purchasing a ZEH that should be recognized in the analysis. The idea is that even without
inflation, $100 today is worth more to a person than the same $100 promised to that
person one year from now, and much more than the same $100 promised ten years from
now. The reason is that that money has an opportunity cost. One could take that same
money and invest it to receive more money in the future; how much money would
depend on the interest rate and many other factors. This could be said about all costs and
benefits. People have a tendency to value costs and benefits incurred today more than
those that they may incur in the future. This is generally why many people purchasing
new homes opt for the Benchmark, where they can receive a new home at the lowest cost
while still being up to code. The reason is that the cost of the ZEH results in a higher
opportunity cost in the present, while at the same time, offering future benefits with a
lower present value. In order to include this concept in the analysis, all monetary values
are converted to their present value, or the equivalent value at the beginning of the
project, or year one. Instead of using an actual interest rate, CEA uses what is known as a
social discount rate (r), for example 0.03 or 0.06. The discount rate is meant to reflect
society’s impatience or preference for consumption today over consumption in the future.
This can sometimes be considered a barrier to entrance into the market.
In CEA, the costs of the project is used as the numerator in the cost-effectiveness
ratio. To do this, all the costs are aggregated in each year, with each years costs as Ct
where t indicates the year from one to T or the last year in the analysis. In this case, “T”
would be at the end of the 30-year mortgage. The values in each year need to be
converted to their year 1 equivalent, which is done by dividing Ct by (1+r)t-1 . For

 

62
 

 

 

example, using a 3% discount rate, $1,000 in costs accruing in year 4, would be
converted to present value by dividing $1,000 by (1.03)3. Summing the present value of
the costs in each year, the present value of costs (PVC) is obtained for the whole project,
as indicated in Figure 8 (Levin and McEwan 2001):

Figure 8. Present value cost formula
The PVC is then used to calculate the CE ratio that was mentioned above.
It is important to note that an appropriate discount rate is critical to a CEA,
however, there is much debate over what rate is appropriate. A study done by the Asian
Development Bank found that developed nations tended to use real rates between three
and seven percent depending on the project, where developing nations used a higher rate
of eight percent or more, reflecting higher risk and uncertainty in investments in those
nations (Wholey, Hatry, and Newcomer 2010). On the other hand, a World Bank paper
has argued for a real rate of 3 to 5 percent (Lopez, 2008). On the far end of the spectrum,
the Stern Report argued for a rate near zero percent for long-term projects involving the
environment (Stern 2006). Thus, there is a broad range of discount rates that can be used
and, in many cases, great resources are poured into determining the appropriate rate. One
of the most common discount rates is three percent, which is what is used in this thesis.
However, we can test the sensitivity of the project by doing sensitivity analysis with
higher rates of five to seven percent.
An additional analysis, one that can goes hand in hand with CEA, is return on
investment (ROI). ROI is an analysis done to calculate the net financial gains or losses of

 

63
 

 

 

a given investment or improvement action, taking into account all the resources invested
and all the amounts gained through an increase in revenue, reduced costs, or both. The
ROI is calculated as the ratio of two financial estimates, as follows:
ROI = net-returns from improvement actions/investment in improvement actions
“Net-returns from improvement actions” refers to financial gains made from the
implementation of the improvements actions. These are generated by net changes in
quality, efficiency, utilization of services, or payments for those services. In this case, it
would refer to the money saved on utility bills due to energy efficiency improvements.
The investment in improvement actions refers to the costs of developing and operating
the improvement actions. This is the cost of the improvements or efficiency upgrades in
our case. In analyzing the ROI Index, a value greater than one means the returns
generated by improvement actions are greater than the costs of implementation. Thus,
ROI is positive in this case. If ROI is less than zero, then improvement actions yield a net
loss from the changes made. This is considered a negative return on investment. Lastly, if
ROI is between zero and one, the improvement actions yielded a positive return from the
changes made, but it is too small to fully recover the implementation costs.
The same data can also be used to calculate the total cost savings of an
improvement by using the following formula:
Cost savings = returns – investment
This is useful to determine whether any money was actually saved over the life of the
investment. For example, would purchasing a ZEH now provide net cost savings, when
all utility bill savings are taken into account over the life of the home? In calculating
ROI, it is also necessary to discount the returns on investment since they are occurring

 

64
 

 

 

over the lifetime of the mortgage, which in this case is 30 years. Thus, the discounted
ROI is reflected in the following formula:
Discounted ROI = net present value benefits/total present value of costs
Additionally, it is of utmost importance that a sensitivity analysis be performed to
test the sensitivity of the analysis to particular assumptions. Sensitivity analysis is an
essential feature of any cost analysis, however, it is less common in the literature than it
should be. A review done by Levin and McEwan (2001) of numerous CE and CB studies
in health showed that two thirds did not conduct a sensitivity analysis. Another found that
only 14% of health studies provided good analysis of uncertainty. If a cost study
completely ignores the issue of uncertainty, the results should be interpreted with some
caution. Even a simple sensitivity analysis is better than none.
For example, a one-way sensitivity analysis is done rather intuitively. First, one
identifies which parameters or inputs reflect the greatest uncertainty. This could be any
aspect of the analysis such as the discount rate, the cost of an ingredient, or the estimate
of effectiveness. Second, one identifies the range over which each parameter might vary.
The middle value is usually the baseline estimate that was calculated in the original
analysis. For example, the cost assumptions used in this thesis are based on national
averages and thus represent a baseline that may vary by region. The high or low values
can be ascertained in a number of ways. Oftentimes, the evaluator uses professional
judgment to estimate the high and low values of the input in question. Parameters that are
derived from statistical analysis of a sample include a confidence interval, whose upper
and lower bounds could be used as the high and low estimates. Once one of the inputs has
been changed, the cost-effectiveness or ROI ratios should be re-estimated for that input,

 

65
 

 

 

with this being repeated for each outcome with an uncertain estimate. The main purpose
for sensitivity analysis is to see if the ranking changes when we change a given
assumption. If cost-effectiveness is invariant with regard to changing assumptions about
any one of the inputs, then the results could be characterized as highly robust with respect
to different assumptions in estimating costs (Levin and McEwan 2001). If, on the other
hand, the ranking of outcomes change with different assumptions, it will be necessary to
decide among alternatives by deciding which assumptions are the most reasonable. If it
seems as though there is great uncertainty, the conclusion may be postponed in order to
seek new sources of data that provide additional certainty.
Lastly, it is often the case that the purpose of doing certain cost analyses is to
make some sort of recommendation in terms of policy or decision-making. In the case of
a CEA, there is no real decision rule when evaluating a given project. Usually
policymakers must use their own judgment as to whether the cost per unit of
effectiveness indicates the need for a decision or in the case of an ROI, whether it is a
solid investment. However, when two or more outcomes are being evaluated against the
same units of effectiveness, the policy with the lowest CE ratio would be indicated.
However, it is not just total costs and benefits that matter when suggesting a policy; who
benefits and who pays are also important. Sometimes it’s difficult to determine whether
there are strong distributional consequences but, if there are, they should be noted. For
example, rising income inequality is a major issue that has made the effects of policy
decisions on low-income populations an essential consideration. In this project, we are
primarily concerned with the costs associated with purchasing a ZEH. However, in terms


 

66
 

 

 

of policy, the cost imposed on all parties is a necessary consideration for all
policymakers.


 

67
 

 

 

Results

The least-cost curve for all nine locations is shown as a function of source energy
savings in Figure 9. At zero source energy savings, the first points on the vertical axis,
represent zero source energy savings i.e., the annual utility bill for a homeowner with a
Building America Benchmark home. Each point along the curve in Figure 9 represents a
different combination of equipment and envelope options for a home. BEopt runs an
annual energy simulation for a large number of possible option combinations in
approximation to the least-cost curve, which represents the lower bound of all the
combination options. While Figure 9 shows only the least-cost curve for each location,
there are many option combinations surrounding the least-cost curve that have near
equivalent costs and performance. While this is not taken into account in this analysis,
these data may be useful in other scenarios where one is interested not only in those
option combinations on the least-cost-curve, but those surrounding it as well.
The marginal cost of increased energy efficiency is equal to the marginal cost of
electricity from residential PV when source energy savings reaches an average of 34.3%.
That is, it becomes cost effective, on average for each location, to implement PV
technology once efficiency measures have brought the house to an energy savings level
of 34.4%. The average was calculated using the points in which PV becomes costeffective for each location. The straight line that begins at source energy savings of
34.3% represents the cost of using a net-metered, grid-connected PV system to meet the
remaining home energy needs on the path to net zero. The minimum average annual
energy-related cost point for all nine locations is $361/year less than the Benchmark and

 

68
 

 

 

occurs on average at 19.4% source energy savings. The average maximum level of source
energy savings occurred at 97.9% with the annualized energy-related costs adding up to
$1,976 more than the Benchmark. As is shown in Figure 9, the benchmarks for each
location begin at different starting points. This is not due to differences in Benchmark
characteristics, but rather differences in climate and energy-related costs associated with
different energy requirements.

Figure 9. Least-cost curve for nine home locations in Washington State

The costs that accrue according to the different levels of source energy savings on
the least-cost curve that go above and beyond the benchmark are reflected in the
annualized energy-related costs. The annualized energy-related costs are calculated by
annualizing all the energy-related cash flows associated with that location over the
analysis period of 30 years, or the life of a typical mortgage. The values displayed in the
least-cost curve, if broken down, include full-annualized utility bills plus incremental

 

69
 

 

 

annualized values for every cash flow. BEopt calculates the cash flows by determining
the mortgage/loan payments, replacements costs, utility bill payments, mortgage tax
deductions, and residual values. The costs, excluding mortgage/loan payments are
inflated using a 3% inflation rate. The annualized costs provide insight into what a
homeowner would actually pay in energy-related costs spread over the lifetime of the
home.
Table 1 provides the cost data that is associated with the least-cost curve in Figure
9. It provides the cost in US dollars of what the annualized energy-related costs would be,
in US dollars, for each location as they reach different points on the path to net zero.
These points include the reference building or benchmark (BAB), 10% energy efficiency
(10%), the minimum cost point (MIN COST), 20% efficiency (20%), the point in which
photovoltaic becomes more cost effective than energy efficiency upgrades (PV START),
and the point in which photovoltaic ends (PV ENDS), which is a modeling limitation,
since BEopt only allows PV systems of up to 8 kW. Nevertheless, additional, often more
costly energy efficiency measures, such as highly insulated walls, could allow a home to
reach zero-energy despite PV sizing limitations. Additional points include 90% energy
efficiency (90%) and the point at which each home reaches its maximum level of energy
efficiency (MAX SAVINGS). The points of MIN COST, PV START, PV END, and
MAX SAVINGS are different for each location and thus the average level of percent
energy savings will be considered for overall results.


 

70
 

 

 

Table 1. Annualized energy-related costs ($/yr.) for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities
BAB 10%
Seattle
1441 1349
Bellingham 1722 1566
Fort Lewis
1709 1557
Olympia
1658 1500
Whidbey
Island
1647 1500
Spokane
1914 1736
Yakima
1796 1635
Port
Angeles
1691 1539
Walla
Walla
1616 1497

MIN
PV
PV
MAX
COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
1317 1349
1477 2935 2978
3662
1492 1494
1683 3132 3210
3694
1494 1495
1693 3174 3585
3727
1445 1447
1652 3137 3518
3709
1418
1652
1585

1420
1666
1600

1549
1788
1690

2956
3140
3011

2913
3099
2979

3575
3731
3640

1454

1459

1598

3019

3016

3644

1453

1487

1620

2929

2888

3598

Table 2. Total marginal costs ($/%) for nine locations on the path to net zero
MIN
PV
PV
MAX
Cities
BAB 10% COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
Seattle
0
839
1317 1349
9419 53419 54829
72143
Bellingham
0
480
2615 2740
12951 56951 59021
71062
Fort Lewis
0
443
2615 2949
13337 57337 67334
71038
Olympia
0
480
2615 2797
12732 56732 66154
71038
Whidbey
Island
0
849
2615 2310
10706 54706 52905
66562
Spokane
0
620
5751 3371
13118 57118 55317
72143
Yakima
0
616
2904 3428
10931 54931 53210
63398
Port
Angeles
0
849
2615 2442
11092 55092 54873
71062
Walla
Walla
0
908
2442 4025
11280 53768 50921
59622

If we were to consider the total costs (Table 2) associated with increasing a
Benchmark home’s efficiency by 10%, we would find it would require an additional $676

 

71
 

 

 

while a 20% increase would be $2,823 more relative to the Benchmark. This 20%
increase in efficiency results in an average annualized cost of $209 less than the
Benchmark. However, if we take into account the average minimum cost point of 19.4%,
we find that it results in an even greater reduction of annualized cost of $361 less than the
Benchmark. While the minimum cost point is just 0.6% below 20% efficiency, it results
in an additional savings of over $150 compared to the homes at 20%. This is because the
minimum cost point is an average of the nine locations with a range of 13.9% to 26.1 %.
However, these findings suggest that a home that cost-optimally achieves a level near
20% source energy savings is actually cheaper than the Benchmark, when the costs are
annualized. At the point in which the marginal cost of energy efficiency equals the
marginal cost of PV-generated electricity, i.e., 34.3%, the total costs increase an average
of $11,720 over the Benchmark. While this may seem like a substantial increase, the
average annualized cost is still less than that of the Benchmark by $49. Thus, one could
potentially build a home that is 30% more efficient relative to the benchmark at an annual
cost that is just slightly less.
The point at which PV ends is averaged around 90.4%, with an average increase
in cost over the Benchmark of $55,561. In annualized terms, this would result in an
average additional cost of $1,360 over the Benchmark. At 90% efficiency, we see an
average increase in total costs of $54,341, with an additional annualized cost over the
Benchmark of $1,653. While 90% efficiency is closely linked to the point in which
Photovoltaic ends at 90.4%, it results in a more expensive annualized cost. This is
because the point at which PV ends is averaged, with a low of 86% and a high of 94.3%,
resulting in a range of costs that brings the annualized cost down. Lastly, the point at

 

72
 

 

 

which max energy savings occurs is averaged at 97.9%, with three locations reaching a
positive net-energy balance Walla Walla, Yakima, and Whidbey Island at 104%, 102.5%,
and 101.1% respectively. The other locations were very near net zero with Seattle at
97.9%, Bellingham at 94.1%, Fort Lewis at 91.1%, Olympia at 91.5%, Spokane at
98.1%, and Port Angeles reaching 98%. The average annual increase in cost over the
Benchmark for the point at which max energy savings occurs for all locations (i.e., the
point at which each location reaches net zero or near net zero) is $1,976 as mentioned
above.
The findings in Table 2 represents the additional cost of energy-efficiency were
one to improve the energy-efficiency of a benchmark home using standard construction
practices until it reaches a level of maximum energy savings or net zero. It does not take
into account the estimated costs of a benchmark building. Thus, the benchmark represents
the reference case for each location and has a total cost of $0. This is consistent with the
BEopt calculations since we are mainly interested in the cost of increasing energyefficiency and not the cost of the reference. On the other hand, in Table 1, the annualized
energy-related costs are calculated for the Benchmark because these data are necessary
for the analysis.
Apart from annualized costs and total costs, annualized utility bills are presented
in Table 3. While Table 1 shows annualized energy-related costs, Table 3 presents
annualized utility bills ($/yr.) for each location on the path to net zero. The first column
in both Tables 1 and 3 contain the same data. This is because they both start where the
benchmark buildings’ annual energy-related costs bare equal to their annual energy bills.
However, once energy-efficiency improvements begin to be made, the trend follows that

 

73
 

 

 

of generally increasing energy-related costs (after reaching the minimum cost point) and
a continually decreasing utility bill (as energy costs are shifted from the utility over to
efficiency measures).
Table 3. Annualized utility bills ($/yr.) for nine locations on the path to net zero
MIN
PV
PV
MAX
Cities
BAB 10% COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
Seattle
1441 1311
1249 1158
1047
476 456
333
Bellingham 1722 1544
1374 1371
1093
513 496
415
Fort Lewis 1709 1537
1376 1363
1086
538 470
448
Olympia
1658 1490
1327 1321
1072
529 459
431
Whidbey
Island
1647 1460
1316 1300
1067
445 485
336
Spokane
1914 1707
1395 1514
1191
514 557
402
Yakima
1796 1606
1454 1444
1193
485 536
400
Port
Angeles
1691 1499
1336 1348
1099
491 497
365
Walla
Walla
1616 1454
1342 1304
1107
453 538
367

Figure 10. Annualized utility bills for nine locations at benchmark

 

74
 

 

 

The effect that increasing energy efficiency has on utility bills is evident when
comparing the annualized utility bills for each location in Figure 10 to those in Figure 11.
Figure 10 represents the annual utility bills for the benchmark at each location. That is, it
is the utility bills for what a typical home built up to code might be for each given
Washington location. Figure 11 represents the annual utility bills for the same locations
after they’ve implemented the most cost-optimal energy efficiency improvements in
order to reach the goal of net zero. The figures break down the annual utility bills by end
use, thus providing insight into the end uses that are most affected by changes in energy
efficiency. As is evident, heating results in the greatest reduction in terms of end uses as
well as contributing the greatest reduction to utility bills.

Figure 11. Annualized utility bills for nine locations at max energy savings
Overall, each location in Washington State took a similar path to net zero as is
indicated in Figure 11. The variation that occurs is due to differences in climate and

 

75
 

 

 

weather patterns for each given location thus resulting in different PV generation and
energy efficiency requirements. Had this project been done for nine locations around the
country, the results would be significantly different. Nevertheless, there is still some
variation with some homes surpassing the net zero goal and others just barely missing it.
The inputs that showed the most variation among the different locations had to do with
the walls, window type and shading, space conditioning, and water heating. However, for
the most part, many of the inputs remained the same as the home designs moved along
the path. For example, all home locations utilized the full 8.0 KW PV systems, which had
a cost of $44,000 for each location. Since PV was necessary to reach net zero, had there
been an option to increase the size of the PV system, it is likely that each home would
have achieved the goal. The PV system also contributed the greatest cost in terms of
energy-efficiency inputs. Also, necessary in reaching net zero was the type of walls used.
In particular, structurally insulated panels (SIPs) or double-studded walls were needed in
several of the cases with a cost of $9,832 and $11,009 respectively, ranking walls as the
second highest cost next to PV. Lastly, the use of solar water heating was also needed in
most cases with a cost of $8,817, which turned out to be the third highest input cost.
Some locations, for instance, Whidbey Island were able to get by without SIPs, which is
reflected in their total cost. These differences in inputs offer great insight into how paths
to the same outcome can be made up of different inputs, which correspond largely with
location.


 

76
 

 

 

Analysis

In order to determine the cost-effectiveness of zero-energy homes in Washington
State, a cost-effectiveness analysis was performed on the cost data generated by BEopt.
As mentioned before, the purpose of a cost-effectiveness analysis is to determine which
alternative or combination of alternatives can achieve a particular objective at the lowest
cost. The underlying assumption is that the different locations of ZEHs in Washington
will have different associated costs and different effects. Thus, we can determine in what
locations might a ZEH be more cost effective. Also, by taking into account multiple
locations throughout Washington State, one can determine the overall cost-effectiveness
of building such homes in Washington by aggregating the data. By understanding the
overall cost-effectiveness and which locations provide the least-cost for a given outcome,
society can use its resources more effectively.
The analysis requires that an ingredients list as well as the associated costs for
each outcome be determined. An outcome, in this case, is defined as a specific point on
the path to net zero. Thus, each location will have several outcomes, represented by the
data in the results. We are interested in which points or outcomes along the least-cost
curve provide the most-cost-effectiveness, i.e., at 20%, 30%. PV STARTS, PV ENDS,
90%, etc. We can determine this by calculating the cost-effectiveness ratios for each
outcome using the costs of each ingredient required for each outcome as well as the
measurement of effectiveness, which, in this project, is the percent of energy saved. The
ingredients or inputs that were used for each location and each simulation were the same
for all locations. The input screen for BEopt is indicated in Figure 12. Differences in

 

77
 

 

 

effects result from differences in weather and climate, which, together, are among the
great determinants of the cost-effectiveness for ZEHs. This has much to do with the need
for renewable generation, particularly photovoltaic, as well as the existence of different
envelope and heating requirements. These three can be the most costly in terms of energy
efficiency upgrades.
To continue the analysis in the same fashion in which the results were presented,
the cost-effectiveness ratios were calculated for each of the nine locations along with 10
different outcomes. The CER was calculated using the total present value costs for each
outcome over the percent of energy saved at that outcome. Thus, cost-effectiveness ratios
for specific levels of percent energy savings (i.e., 10%, 20%, 90%) were calculated using
the given percent as the denominator. However, for outcomes with different percent
energy savings (i.e., MIN COST, PV START, PV END, MAX SAVINGS), the percent
energy savings that was achieved for each outcome per location was used as the
denominator. Nevertheless, we are able to determine, for each outcome, what home
locations are the most cost-effective. Table 4 presents the cost-effectiveness ratios for
each outcome per location. The CER represents the cost per unit of effectiveness or in
other words, the cost per unit of percent energy saved (i.e., $/% energy savings).


 

78
 

 

 

Figure 12. BEopt input screen indicating the ingredients (inputs) used for each location.
(Single selections indicate inputs that were held constant)

 

79
 

 

 

Table 4. Cost-effectiveness ratios ($/%) for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities
BAB 10%
Seattle
0 83.9
Bellingham
0
48
Fort Lewis
0 44.3
Olympia
0
48
Whidbey
Island
0 84.9
Spokane
0
62
Yakima
0 61.6
Port
Angeles
0 84.9
Walla
Walla
0 90.8

MIN
PV
PV
MAX
COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
86
67
319
601 609
694
131 137
356
642 656
725
136 147
366
666 748
696
133 140
361
660 735
724
125
220
160

116
169
171

309
349
326

586
618
583

588
615
591

659
788
696

126

122

322

610

610

755

153

201

356

570

566

609

Depending on the location and the outcome, different cost-effectiveness ratios
were calculated using the formula in the methods. What we find is that although most
locations follow the same general pattern in terms of increasing CERs as % energy
savings increases (see Figure 13), their CERS are different from each other with the same
outcomes. For all locations at the Benchmark or reference outcome, the CERs were $0/%
energy savings. At 10% energy savings, the most cost-effective location is Fort Lewis
with a CER of $44.30/% energy savings. The least-cost-effective location is Walla Walla
Washington with a CER of $90.80/% energy savings. For the minimum cost outcome,
Seattle has the lowest CER of $86.10/% energy savings. This is only $2.10 more than
Seattle’s CER at 10%, however, Seattle reached its minimum cost outcome at the lowest
percent of energy savings, which was 15.3%. The least-cost effective at the minimum
cost outcome was Spokane at $220/% energy savings. However, Spokane was able to
reach their minimum cost point at the highest percent of energy savings compared to all


 

80
 

 

 

locations, which was 26.1%. This explains why, in Figure 13, Spokane’s CER is so much
higher than the rest.

Figure 13. Cost-effectiveness ratios for nine locations on the path to net zero

It is also important to note that the average minimum cost point for all locations
was 19.4%, which is very close to the 20% outcome of all locations. However, there is
noticeable variation between some of the CERs at the minimum cost outcome and the
20% outcome because of the differences in how each location was able to reach its

 

81
 

 

 

minimum cost. For example, at the 20% outcome, the most cost-effective location is
Seattle with a CER of $67/% energy savings. The least cost-effective at 20% was Walla
Walla with a CER of $201/% energy saving. The next most cost-effective location after
Seattle was Whidbey Island with a CER of $116/% energy savings, indicating that
Seattle, at the 20% outcome, is significantly more cost-effective than the other locations.
Interestingly, Seattle was one of the least-cost effective at 10%.
At the outcome in which the marginal cost of increased energy efficiency is equal
to the marginal cost of electricity from residential PV (i.e., PV START), the most costeffective location is Whidbey Island with a CER of $309/% energy savings. The average
point at which PV becomes cost-effective to implement is 34.3%, with Whidbey Island
implementing it at 34.7%. The least cost-effective is Fort Lewis with a CER of $366/%
energy savings and achieving this at 36.4%. As we move to the outcome at which PV
ends, or the point where the 8.0 KW PV system maxes out, we find that the most costeffective location is Walla Walla with a CER of $570/% energy savings. The least-cost
effective for this outcome is still Fort Lewis with a CER of $666/% energy savings. The
average point in which PV ends for all locations is 90.4%, with Walla Walla stretching it
to the maximum level of efficiency at 94.3% and Fort Lewis reaching it at the lowest,
86%. This explains why some of the locations have CERs at PV END that are very
similar to the levels reached at the 90% outcome. For example, in Figure 13, Olympia
and Fort Lewis show the greatest increase in their CERs from PV END to 90%, which is
mainly due to their photovoltaic systems both ending at 86%, whereas the rest were near
90% or above. The 90% outcome results in Walla Walla achieving the greatest cost-


 

82
 

 

 

effectiveness with a CER of $566/% energy savings and Fort Lewis achieving the leastcost effective CER at $748/% energy savings.
Perhaps the most significant CERs calculated are those relating to the maximum
level of energy savings or net zero-energy homes. The average maximum level of energy
savings for all locations was achieved at 97.9%. The location with the most costeffectiveness is Wall Walla, with a CER of $609/% energy savings and a max energy
savings of 104%, resulting in a positive net zero-energy home. The least cost-effective
was Spokane, with a CER of $788/% energy savings while reaching a total energy
savings of 98.1%. It is also interesting to note that both Fort Lewis and Yakima had
CERs of $696/% energy savings, while reaching energy savings levels of 91.1% and
102.5%, respectively. This goes to show that although a given location has the potential
to achieve 100% zero energy, it may not be the most cost-effective location in which to
do so.
800
 
700
 
Cost
 ($)
 Per
 Unit
  600
 
of
 Effectiveness
  500
 
(%
 Energy
 
400
 
Savings)
 
300
 

 
200
 
100
 
0
 

615
  635
 

705
 

340
 

0
 

67.6
 

141
  141
 

WA
 State
 

Outcomes
 Along
 the
 Path
 to
 Net-­‐Zero
 

Figure 14. Cost-effectiveness for homes on the path to net zero in Washington State
Taking the average CERs for each outcome, we are left with a generalized costeffectiveness for the state of Washington, based on nine locations throughout the state.

 

83
 

 

 

Looking at Figure 14, we can see the average cost per unit of effectiveness as we move
along the path to net zero. Starting with a benchmark building, at 0% energy savings, the
line graph covers each major outcome along the path to net zero. The average CERs are
indicated above each outcome near the line. One sees that the cost-effectiveness of
energy-efficiency improvements decreases the further you move along the path to net
zero. That is, as a home continually becomes more energy-efficient, the cost of each
additional percent of energy saved costs more than the last due to the increase in cost of
more expensive technologies. However, most of the increase in the CER is seen after
photovoltaic is implemented, which makes sense, since it is the most costly energy
efficient upgrade. At the same time, PV also provides renewable energy, thus driving the
cost of utility bills down and providing a payback on investment. This isn’t reflected in
the CER because it only takes into account what it costs per unit of energy-efficiency to
build a home along the path to net zero and not the payback provided by lower utility
bills over the life of the mortgage. This is more accurately reflected in a Return on
Investment Analysis (ROI), which is discussed in the methods, and will now be
presented.
The ROI was calculated using data from Tables 2 and 3. Table 2 provides the
annualized utility bill costs for all locations at each point along the path to net zero. This
table includes the annualized utility bills for the benchmark at each location as well as the
utility bills for each level of energy savings. In order to calculate how much is being
saved at each point along the path, the utility bill costs at each point were deducted from
the benchmark utility, to get the total annual utility bill savings from energy-efficiency
upgrades at each point. Since this is money that is being saved, it represents a return on

 

84
 

 

 

the investment. While it may not seem like much initially, the money saved on utility
bills adds up over the life of a mortgage and, thus, is a good estimate of how cost
effective an investment will be over its life. Since purchasing a home is often the biggest
investment people make in their lives, it makes sense to determine what kind of return
they could receive by purchasing a ZEH. Table 5 provides the discounted (0.03) present
value of utility bill savings over the 30-year life of the mortgage. It is the amount of
money, in present-value terms, which one could expect to save on utility bills for each
home design along the path to net zero.
Table 5. Net present value of total utility bills savings on the path to net zero
Cities
Seattle
Bellingham
Fort Lewis
Olympia
Whidbey
Island
Spokane
Yakima
Port
Angeles
Walla
Walla

MIN
COST 20%
3763 5547
6821 6880
6527 6782
6488 6605

PV
START
7723
12329
12211
11486

PV END
18914
23697
22952
22129

90%
19306
24030
24285
23501

MAX
SAVINGS
21717
25618
24716
24050

6801
7840
6899

11368
14171
11819

23560
27441
25696

22776
26598
24697

25696
29636
27362

6958

6723

11603

23521

23403

25990

5371

6115

9977

22795

21129

24481

BAB
0
0
0
0

10%
2548
3489
3371
3293

0
0
0

3665
4057
3724

6488
10173
6703

0

3763

0

3175

Once the values in Table 5 were calculated, the figures in Table 2 were used to
determine the ROI for each point along the path to net zero. Since ROI is calculated using
the formula: Discounted ROI = net present value benefits/total present value of costs , we
determined ROI by dividing the figures in Table 5 by the corresponding figures in Table
2. Thus, total utility bills savings were divided by the total marginal costs of energy
efficiency upgrades to give us Table 6, the ROI index for each point along the path to net
zero. The ROI index is a number that represents the point at which an investment has

 
85
 

 

 

paid for itself and is designed to simplify and standardize return on investment. An ROI
index of 0.5, for example, means that the improvement action recovered 50% of its costs.
An ROI index of 1 means that the investment has paid for itself in full, but the savings
did not exceed the investment. An ROI index greater than 1 means that savings exceeds
investment. For example, an index of 3 means that the savings have reached 3 times the
amount of the investment. Thus, if we look at Table 6, we can see that at 10% energy
efficiency, all locations recovered the costs several times over, with Fort Lewis providing
the best ROI. At MIN COST, the ROI for all locations except Spokane was greater than
2, resulting in a return greater than twice the amount of the investment.
Table 6. Return on investment for nine locations on the path to net zero
10%

MIN
COST

20%

PV
START

PV
END

90%

MAX
SAVINGS

Cities

BAB

Seattle

0.00

3.04

2.86

4.11

0.82

0.35

0.35

0.30

Bellingham
Fort Lewis
Olympia
Whidbey
Island
Spokane
Yakima
Port
Angeles
Walla
Walla

0.00
0.00
0.00

7.27
7.61
6.86

2.61
2.50
2.48

2.51
2.30
2.36

0.95
0.92
0.90

0.42
0.40
0.39

0.41
0.36
0.36

0.36
0.35
0.34

0.00
0.00
0.00

4.32
6.54
6.05

2.48
1.77
2.31

2.94
2.33
2.01

1.06
1.08
1.08

0.43
0.48
0.47

0.43
0.48
0.48

0.39
0.41
0.43

0.00

4.43

2.66

2.75

1.05

0.43

0.43

0.37

0.00

3.50

2.20

1.52

0.88

0.42

0.41

0.41

At 20%, the investment in energy-efficiency is still cost-effective in terms of ROI,
with all but Walla Walla having an index greater than 2. At PV START, where the
average level of energy efficiency is 34.3%, 4 of the 5 homes had an ROI Index greater
than 1, while least-cost-effective was Walla Walla with an Index of 0.88. As we move
into greater levels of energy-efficiency, it becomes clear that the investment becomes less

 

86
 

 

 

appealing. This is primarily due to the increase in costs of technology, particularly PV,
relative to the payback provided by savings on utilities. As is shown above, after PV
ENDS until MAX SAVINGS for all locations, the ROI index is below 0.5 for all
locations. Thus, after PV START, or an average energy savings level of 34.3%, the
energy efficient upgrades do not provide a significant payback.
Figure 15 shows these data more clearly as an average ROI for the state, while
Figure 16 presents a bar graph of ROI for each location. These figures show that, at every
energy savings level, there is a return, although in the cases of highest energy efficiency
this tends to be less than a 50% payback. In both representations, it becomes clear that the
10% energy savings level provides the greatest return on investment by a substantial
amount compared to all other levels of savings. The only case where it does not is Seattle,
where 20% energy savings provides the best ROI. This could suggest that Seattle is the
best place to invest in a home at that energy savings level. It also suggests that anything
before PV implementation is going to provide a positive return, i.e., greater than 1. This
suggests that in the future, as the price of PV comes down, return on investment will rise.
6
 
5
 
4
 
Average
 ROI
 
3
 
Index
 
2
 
1
 
0
 

Outcomes
 along
 the
 Path
 to
 Net-­‐Zero
 

Figure 15. Average ROI index for nine locations on the path to net zero

 

87
 

 

 

8.00
 
7.00
 
6.00
 
BAB
 

5.00
 

10%
 

4.00
 

MIN
 COST
 

ROI
 Index
 
3.00
 

 

20%
 
PV
 START
 

2.00
 

PV
 END
 
1.00
 

90%
 
MAX
 SAVINGS
 

0.00
 

Washington
 State
 Location
 for
 ZEH
 Designs
 

Figure 16. Return on investment index for nine locations on the path to net zero
Lastly, a sensitivity analysis was performed on the data for both CEA and ROI to
gauge levels of uncertainty and to see how changing assumptions could lead to changes
in results. This approach varies one assumption at a time, holding everything else
constant. For example, in the case of the CEA, we assumed no incentives in our cost
calculations for the implementation of our photovoltaic systems. However, there
currently exists a federal residential renewable energy tax credit that could be applied to
the price of this PV system, thus lowering the overall marginal cost of a home design
once it reaches the point at which PV becomes cost-effective (DSIRE 2012). This federal
tax credit applies to solar water heat, photovoltaic, wind, fuel cells, geothermal heat
pumps, other solar electric technologies, as well as fuel cells using renewable fuels. The

 

88
 

 

 

tax credit applies to 30% of the total price, with no maximum size for solar electric
systems placed in service after 2008. This tax credit expirees on December 31, 2016 and,
so, would apply only to those systems installed within the next few years, unless the tax
credit is extended. Using this renewable tax credit to test our initial analysis, we deduct
30% from the price of the PV installation for each location at PV END, 90%, and MAX
SAVINGS. At these points along the path to net zero, the full 8.0 kW PV system was
needed to reach the energy savings level, with a total cost of $44,000 for the system.
Thus, 30% deducted from the total price of the installed PV system at $44,000 is
$13,200. This is a substantial savings and one that could realistically apply. See Table 7
for adjusted total costs.
Table 7. Total costs — 30% tax credit for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities

BAB

10%
839
480
443
480
849

MIN
COST
1317
2615
2615
2615
2615

Seattle
Bellingham
Fort Lewis
Olympia
Whidbey
Island
Spokane
Yakima
Port
Angeles
Walla
Walla

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

620
616
849

0

908

20%
1349
2740
2949
2797
2310

PV
START
9419
12951
13337
12732
10706

PV
END
40219
43751
44137
43532
41506

90%
41629
45821
54134
52954
39705

MAX
SAVINGS
58943
57862
57838
57838
53362

5751
2904
2615

3371
3428
2442

13118
10931
11092

43918
41731
41892

42117
40010
41673

58943
50198
57862

2442

4025

11280

40568

37721

46422

After adjusting the total price for those points that utilized PV, we also calculated
the cost-effectiveness ratio for each as well, which is indicated in Table 8. As is shown
below, the CERs only changed for PV END, 90%, and MAX SAVINGS, with all
locations having the same reduction in price and thus an equivalent reduction in their

 

89
 

 

 

cost-effectiveness. Nevertheless, this could significantly impact decision-making in terms
of a maximum level of cost-effectiveness. For example, if someone was limited to a CER
of 600, then under our original analysis, they could not afford to reach the level of energy
efficiency attained at PV END and beyond. However, under our sensitivity analysis, they
could now afford a home in several locations that achieve MAX SAVINGS. The only
locations, in which they could not, would be Spokane and Port Angeles. Under the
original analysis, they could only reach PV END and only in a limited number of
locations, i.e., Whidbey Island, Yakima, and Walla Walla. Thus, adjusting the price of
PV can significantly impact the cost-effectiveness for those homes beyond PV START.
However, adjusting for the tax credit did not affect the ranking of the locations, indicating
the results hold despite changes in the greatest cost determiner. Figure 14 indicates the
change in the average CERs for Washington, which follows the same path as Figure 12.

Table 8. CERs adjusted for 30% tax credit for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities
BAB 10%
Seattle
0
83.9
Bellingham
0
48
Fort Lewis
0
44.3
Olympia
0
48
Whidbey
Island
0
84.9
Spokane
0
62
Yakima
0
61.6
Port
Angeles
0
84.9
Walla
Walla
0
90.8

MIN
PV
PV
MAX
COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
86
67
319
452
463
567
131
137
356
493
509
590
136
147
366
513
601
567
133
140
361
506
588
590
125
220
160

116
169
171

309
349
326

445
475
443

441
468
445

528
644
551

126

122

322

464

463

615

153

201

356

430

419

474


 

90
 

 

 

Cost
 Effectiveness
 for
 Homes
 on
 the
 
Path
 to
 Net-­‐
 Zero
 in
 WA
 
 
Cost
 ($)
 Per
 Unit
 
of
 
Effectiuveness
 
(%
 Energy
 
Savings)
 
Adjusted
 for
 
30%
 Tax
 Credit
 

600
 
500
 
400
 
300
 
200
 
100
 
0
 

469
  489
 

570
 

340
 

0
 

67.6
 

141
  141
 
WA
 State
 

Outcomes
 Along
 the
 Path
 to
 Net-­‐Zero
 

Figure 17. Adjusted cost-effectiveness for homes on the path to net zero
An additional sensitivity analysis was performed by adjusting the discount rates
for the data in the return on investment analysis. Taking a 1% and 5% discount rate, we
can see what a 2% change in either direction would look like. Since the payback, in terms
of utility bill savings, is highly dependent on the value we place on future payments,
changing the discount rate could provide very different results. Table 9 represents the
ROI index with a discount rate of 1%. This would represent someone who places a very
high value on the money that they will receive in the future. A discount rate of 0% would
represent placing the same value on returns several years from now as one would today.
There are reasons to value returns differently and, in fact, depending on the party,
discount rates could vary widely. Perhaps, someone who values the environment would
value the future returns from utility bill savings more highly because it includes a nonmonetized value of emission reduction on their part. Thus, at 1%, ZEHs could provide a
substantial ROI as indicated in Table 9.

 

91
 

 

 

Table 9. ROI index (1% discount rate) for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities
Seattle
Bellingham
Fort Lewis
Olympia
Whidbey
Island
Spokane
Yakima
Port
Angeles
Walla
Walla

BAB 10%
0.00
9.11
0.00 21.81
0.00 22.83
0.00 20.58

MIN
PV
PV
MAX
COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
8.57 12.34
2.46
1.06 1.06
0.90
7.83
7.53
2.86
1.25 1.22
1.08
7.49
6.90
2.75
1.20 1.08
1.04
7.44
7.08
2.71
1.17 1.07
1.02

0.00
0.00
0.00

12.95
19.63
18.14

7.44
5.31
6.92

8.83
6.98
6.04

3.19
3.24
3.24

1.29
1.44
1.40

1.29
1.44
1.44

1.16
1.23
1.29

0.00

13.30

7.98

8.26

3.14

1.28

1.28

1.10

0.00

10.49

6.60

4.56

2.65

1.27

1.24

1.23

Under this scenario, we find that every location at every point, except for Seattle
at MAX SAVINGS, provides an ROI greater than 1. Thus, if someone were to place a
high value on utility bill savings over the life of the home, a ZEH or one on the path to
net zero could provide a complete return on investment in nearly all cases. It was also the
case that changing the discount rate does not change the ranking of any location at any
point. As is shown, 10% energy savings still provides the greatest ROI, with Bellingham,
Olympia, and Fort Lewis achieving returns 20 times greater than what was invested.
While changing the discount rate had no effect on ranking, it is a good test of
sensitivity, in that it points out how important the discount rate can be in terms of making
decisions that involve future payouts. This is even more apparent when we apply a
discount rate of 5% as is shown in Table 10. A 5% discount results in greatly reduced
ROIs, with no locations receiving a positive return at PV Start, whereas before 4 of the 5
locations were able to. Additionally, all location were able to achieve a ROI greater than
1 at 20% energy savings before, whereas now, Walla Walla, does not. Nevertheless, the

 

92
 

 

 

rankings still do not change, as was the case with the 1% discount rate. This can be seen
more clearly by comparing Figure 16 and Figure 18.
Table 10. ROI Index (5% discount rate) for nine locations on the path to net zero
Cities
BAB 10%
Seattle
0.00
1.82
Bellingham
0.00
4.36
Fort Lewis
0.00
4.57
Olympia
0.00
4.12
Whidbey
Island
0.00
2.59
Spokane
0.00
3.93
Yakima
0.00
3.63
Port
Angeles
0.00
2.66
Walla Walla
0.00
2.10

MIN
PV
PV
MAX
COST 20% START END 90% SAVINGS
1.71
2.47
0.49 0.21 0.21
0.18
1.57
1.51
0.57 0.25 0.24
0.22
1.50
1.38
0.55 0.24 0.22
0.21
1.49
1.42
0.54 0.23 0.21
0.20
1.49
1.06
1.38

1.77
1.40
1.21

0.64
0.65
0.65

0.26
0.29
0.28

0.26
0.29
0.29

0.23
0.25
0.26

1.60
1.32

1.65
0.91

0.63
0.53

0.26
0.25

0.26
0.25

0.22
0.25

5.00
 
4.00
 
BAB
 
3.00
 

ROI
 Index
 

 

10%
 
MIN
 COST
 

2.00
 

20%
 

1.00
 

PV
 START
 
PV
 END
 

0.00
 

90%
 
MAX
 SAVINGS
 
Washington
 State
 Location
 for
 ZEH
 Designs
 

Figure 18. ROI (5% discount rate) for nine locations on the path to net zero


 

93
 

 

 

In conclusion, Figures 14 and 15 provide an overall average summary of costeffectiveness and return on investment for zero-energy homes in Washington State. It is
clear from the data that cost-effectiveness decreases as the percent in energy savings
increases. That is, as homes become increasingly energy-efficient the price per unit of
effectiveness - in this case, price per percent energy savings - continues to increase as
well. This is particularly significant after PV begins to be implemented as is noted by the
sharp rise in the CER after PV START. This large decrease in the cost-effectiveness is
primarily the result of the PV systems, after PV START, since these payments represent
such a large portion of the overall cost of energy-efficiency improvements. This is also
the reason why the CER before PV START is fairly low, with it more than doubling by
the time it reaches PV END. It is also important to note that the rise in CER levels off
after PV END to a very gradual increase, ending at MAX SAVINGS. Thus, it would be
most beneficial for the government or any party interested in increasing the costeffectiveness of ZEHs, to focus on research and policy that would contribute to lowering
the cost of photovoltaic systems. This is because PV systems result in the greatest
increase in CERs as well as the largest portion of overall costs. As is shown in our
sensitivity analysis, the federal tax credit substantially lowered the CER for the homes in
which PV was implemented, simply by providing a tax incentive.
However, while cost-effectiveness allows us to see the incremental increase in
cost per unit of effectiveness, it does not provide the consumer with enough information
to make an informed investment decision. Since it is often consumers, and not the
government, that drive changes in the marketplace; it may be the consumers that drive the
production of new zero-energy homes. Thus, it is necessary that we get information such

 

94
 

 

 

as the ROI of ZEH into the hands of those that could use it. This is helpful because, as
one can see in Figure 15, investing in energy-efficient homes does provide significant
payback. It is clear here that the greatest returns are provided early on at 10% energy
efficiency and slowly decline until the investment drops below full reimbursement near
PV START, which makes sense, since PV implementation results in the greatest increase
in the total cost of investment. However, this is largely dependent on how we value the
future payback in terms of utility bill savings. For someone who places a much higher
value on their dollar today than that dollar tomorrow, then ZEHs may not be a very good
investment. However, for someone who places a much higher value on their future utility
bill savings because they represent a lower carbon footprint, then ZEHs may be a very
successful investment. Although this analysis makes many assumptions, it is essential to
do these sorts of calculations if we are to provide credible and informative information on
the capabilities and potentialities of ZEHs as well as providing insight for new and
innovative policy measures.


 

95
 

 

 

Discussion

The purpose of this research was to determine the cost-effectiveness of ZEHs in
Washington State. After taking the results into account, it is clear that energy-efficiency
can be cost-effective and could provide a return on the investment, particularly for levels
before PV START or an average energy-efficiency level of 34.3%. This is primarily due
to the cost of photovoltaic systems being what they are despite this technology becoming
increasing less expensive. Nevertheless, this research has shown that energy-efficiency
does pay, not only in terms of financial benefits but in positive environmental impacts as
well. Thus, while we may not see ZEHs become implemented on a production basis right
away, it is important that we work to make our homes more energy-efficient than the
Benchmark building or code-compliant house.
Furthermore, it should be noted that all assumptions in this thesis inherently leave
room for uncertainty and while a sensitivity analysis was performed on the data, changing
the assumptions of this project would undoubtedly change the results to a degree. For
example, had the definition of ZEHs been changed from source energy to site energy, the
use of a source-to-site-ratio would not have been permitted and the need for a larger PV
array would have been required to reach the same outcomes. Additionally, the benchmark
home could have been user defined, in which case, every result would have been
different. This is because all home designs begin at the benchmark and move upward
through energy-efficiency to reach net zero. Thus, a different benchmark would have
resulted in different housing requirements and, in turn, different starting utility rates. Also
part of the benchmark, were the user profiles, which were based on a typical occupancy

 

96
 

 

 

behavior. Such user profiles could have been changed to reflect more conservative
behavior and thus result in a home that could have reached net zero earlier on the path.
The same could be said for changing the comfort heating and cooling set points so that
they reflected a cooler/warmer environment. Changes in the study period, or length of
mortgage, from 30 years to a different length of time would affect the results,
particularly, in terms of return on investment.
Apart from changes in the study period, changes in the interest rate, inflation rate,
and discount rate can have significant effects on the costs, especially as they change over
time. An example of changing the discount rate was presented in the sensitivity analysis,
which showed great degrees of change in terms of return on investment. Lastly, changing
in the floor plan used in this thesis, or of any housing characteristics, such as compass
direction, size of eaves, house size, etc., that were held constant, could change the entire
parameters of the study. Thus, while the benchmark used in this thesis is representative of
a typical conventional American home, the assumptions associated with it may not be
representative of all homes in Washington. Nevertheless, projections, as are provided by
the results of modeling studies, would not be possible without certain assumptions. They
allow us to predict in what ways we can reach certain levels of energy efficiency and at
what cost. This type of information is invaluable when it comes to implementing energy
efficiency, particularly at the state and national levels.
One of the most effective ways of accomplishing energy efficiency in the building
sector is through the adoption and implementation of energy efficient building codes i.e.,
energy codes. It is through the use of these codes that we have a viable avenue of
softening the environmental impact of buildings as well as generating energy and cost

 

97
 

 

 

savings that extend far into the future. These codes are also responsible for driving much
of the wide scale implementation of energy efficiency in buildings, even though much of
the public is unaware of this until they are confronted with purchasing a new home or
renovating an existing one. Even then, the long term benefits and/or additional cost may
not be completely understood by current and prospective homeowners. Those not “in the
know” might consider these codes unnecessary or too costly. It is true that they can come
at an additional cost, but the costs offer paybacks, not only in terms of energy saved, but
also in the reduction of climate impacts and the protection of our environment. This is
clear after looking at the data analysis done in this thesis, particularly for the lower
energy savings levels.
Energy codes establish the criteria for a buildings thermal envelope, HVAC
systems (heating, ventilation, and air conditioning), water heating systems, lighting, and
other areas dealing with energy use. These codes serve as a baseline from which both
residential and commercial buildings can achieve a minimum level of energy-efficiency.
The two most commonly adopted energy codes are the International Energy Conservation
Code (IECC) and ANSI/ASHRAE/IES standard 90.1 (ASHRAE 90.1). The IECC can be
applied to all buildings while ASHRE 90.1 only applies to commercial buildings. Both
IECC and ASHRAE standard 90.1 are maintained and updated in open public forums.
This kind of transparency is of utmost importance to the widespread acceptance of the
resulting energy codes. Those participating in the maintenance and upkeep of these
energy codes include a wide array of interests. Representatives from the design
community, code enforcement community, policy makers, builders, industry, utilities,
advocacy groups, academia, and federal agencies, such as the DOE, are all involved

 

98
 

 

 

(DOE 2010). Through collaboration, all stakeholders have an opportunity to participate
and voice their technological, economic, and policy concerns as they relate to the
maintenance of the codes. Without organizations like ICC and ASHRAE, each
government agency, from federal down to the local government, would need to develop
its own, similar standards. This would lead to an immeasurable amount of additional
work and would threaten code uniformity, which is essential for the building industry.
Thankfully, the development and maintenance process of these model codes and
standards is not as much of a concern as is the adoption of these codes.
In the United States, there is no national energy codes or standard. This means
that the responsibility of adopting model codes, such as the IECC and ASHRAE 90.1 fall
to the state and local levels of government. Adoption occurs through legislative action or
regulatory agencies authorized by the legislative body. Once they are adopted through
regulation, the building energy codes become law within that state or local jurisdiction.
At the federal level, the DOE’s Building Energy Codes Program (BECP) provides the
technical support to state and local governments in order to help assist in the adoption
process (DOE 2010). This assistance includes energy savings and cost analysis,
comparative analysis of future code options, potential modification of model code,
educational materials, training, and compliance resources. They also provide a State
Energy Program (SEP) that provides grants to states so that they may carry out their own
renewable and energy-efficiency programs.
While the main goal of energy codes is to conserve energy, there are a number of
additional benefits that are also realized. From the national government to states and local
municipalities, all the way down to the homeowner, there are a range of energy,

 

99
 

 

 

economic, and environmental benefits to be had from energy codes. This has been
recognized by the national government, and, although there is no national building code,
Congress has been trying for decades to encourage states and local authorities to adopt
progressively stronger energy codes for all new buildings. Two major contributing
statutes are the 1992 Energy Policy Act, which directs the states to consider the model
residential energy code (IECC) and to adopt the model commercial energy code
(ASHRAE standard or equivalent) with updates (U.S. House 1992) The other is the
American Recovery and Investment Act of 2009, which requires states to commit to
adopting and improving compliance with the 2007 ASHRAE Standard and the 2009
IECC as a condition for receiving their share of the $3.2 billion State Energy Program
grants (U.S. House 2009).
Thus, while there are many recognized benefits of adopting energy efficient
building codes, this doesn’t necessarily mean that the benefits will lead to adoption. This
has to do with the fact that every benefit comes at a cost and sometimes states or
localities must weigh them according to their own goals and motivations. This is partly
why one of the most easily recognized and appreciated benefits is the substantial money
savings that results from the adoption of energy codes. It is estimated that building codes
could potentially produce a financial benefit to homeowners of $2 billion annually by
2015, rising to $15 billion by 2030 (DOE 2013). This is the result of saving over 14
quadrillion Btu of energy from 2009 to 2030. Studies also show that transforming the
building sector so that it employs more energy efficient designs and equipment as well as
solar could cut projected household energy expenses from $285 billion down to $130
billion by 2030. While there could be a modest initial increase in cost for these

 

100
 

 

 

improvements, the investment will offer a payback in lower energy bills and even make
homes more affordable to the consumer by lowering their total monthly cost i.e.
mortgage plus utility bills. This initial increase in cost for a new home often pays for
itself in as little as 12 months (Mississippi Development Authority 2013). In California,
the state has saved businesses and residents more than $15.8 billion in electricity and
natural gas costs since 1975, with these savings expected to climb to $59 billion in 2011
(EPA 2012) Apart from the obvious savings, however, energy-efficient buildings can also
result in reduced maintenance costs. These result from improvements that reduce total
building maintenance due, for example, to problems that occur from condensation,
excessive runtimes of heating/cooling equipment, pest infestations from improper
sealing, and the additional cost that comes from fixing such problems post construction.
On the other hand, failing to take advantage of the building sectors potential savings
could raise the cost of meeting our long-term climate goals by at least $500 billion per
year globally (Houser 2009).
With climate change as a major motivation for many entities to adopt energy
codes, the resulting emission reductions also become a great benefit. Buildings use a
significant amount of energy and thus result in a significant amount of pollution,
particularly carbon from our substantial coal use in electricity generation. Projected
savings from energy code adoption could reach 800 million metric tons of CO2 by 2030,
which is equivalent to removing 145 million vehicles from our roadways (DOE 2013). It
was also found that states that adopted the federal building energy codes reduced
household GHG emissions by 16% from 1986 to 2008 (DOE 2013). States are also
realizing the benefits of reducing pollution through energy efficiency. The New York

 

101
 

 

 

Energy Conservation Construction Code (ECCC) reduces CO2 emissions by more than
500,000 tons annually and reduces SO2 by nearly 500 tons per year (EPA 2006). Also,
the 2001 Texas Building Energy Performance Standards are projected to reduce nitrogen
oxide emissions statewide by more than two tons each peak day and over one ton each
average day, which helps the state meet Clean Air Act requirements for nonattainment
areas (EPA 2006). While it may be difficult to quantify these benefits in monetary
amounts, they are still a great benefit of energy codes particularly in regards to climate
change goals.
Building energy codes also provide jobs and economic stability as a benefit. The
use of innovative and improved technology in buildings and the need for energy code
experts will create new job opportunities around the country. New codes means new
technical experts will be required in areas such as duct and air leakage, quality control,
building and systems commissioning, energy auditing, and compliance (DOE 2013).
Even requirements for retrofitting and weatherization could create new employment
opportunities. Also, instead of sending money out of the state, as is often the case with
energy services, dollars saved from efficiency tend to be re-spent locally, thus booting the
economy (EPA 2012). As for the consumer, reducing heating and cooling costs allows
more money to be saved and thus spent on other good and services, which are essential to
a healthy economy. The same also goes for business owners who have more money to
spend on business improvements such as additional investments or employee benefits.
Another aspect of building codes is that that they have the potential to support grid
reliability through system sizing and increased controls. By decreasing the impact of peak
loads, these codes help reduce the stress on the grid, thus creating a reliable grid and a

 

102
 

 

 

reliable economy. When the lights are out, it is hard to keep things running. Lastly,
reducing our nations dependency on foreign energy sources is one of the greatest benefits
energy codes can have on our economy. In a global market, things can be hard to predict
and control, so making us less reliant on other country’s resources secures our economic
stability.
Additional benefits are realized come from the positive health aspects of energy
codes. By reducing pollution, including GHG emissions, and by improving the indoor air
quality of buildings, energy codes keep consumers comfortable and healthy. The Center
for Disease Control and Prevention found that burning fossil fuels contributes to
numerous health issues such as asthma, bronchitis, pneumonia, and low birth rate (CDC
2013). As a result, people that may not have gotten sick under lower emissions levels
may end up at the hospital, resulting in higher health costs overall. By reducing our fossil
fuel emissions we can actually lower the risk of related health problems. Apart from the
environmental pollutants, energy-efficient buildings often reduce other health risks from
things like mold, dust, radon, pollen, rodents, insects, and combustion products
(Mississippi Development Authority 2013). These health concerns are often seen in old
houses and those that are not up to code. Further health benefits arise from the fact that
energy codes result in a more comfortable home and can help alleviate problems with
outdoor noise, muggy air, condensation, and hot and cold areas. These examples go to
show that improving building efficiency in energy codes can have far-reaching benefits
that extend all the way to anyone who interacts with our built environments i.e., basically
everyone.


 

103
 

 

 

While there are numerous benefits that these continual energy code improvements
provide, they do not come without a price. Improving efficiency requires making new
investments and making investments requires spending money now so that we may save
or make money in the future. Thus, one way to understand building codes is to think of
them as an investment. They are an investment that provides numerous benefits,
including energy and cost savings, but at the same time, must come with an initial
increase in cost. With each new model code, the Department of Energy performs its own
evaluation to determine whether the new codes will actually save energy and, in turn,
save money. If it weren’t required that building codes utilize a minimum level of costeffectiveness, then they would likely be extremely difficult to implement and enforce.
However, as it turns out, building codes are one of the most fundamental, affordable, and
effective methods for increasing long-term efficiency of our nations buildings despite any
increase in costs they may have. It is a great misconception that upgrading our building
energy codes requires an increase in cost that is not easily offset. While it is true that
building a home to meet a new code or retrofitting an old house up to code is going to
cost more, this increase will quickly be paid back through lower utility bills. The longterm savings this provides will actually make the energy-efficient home more affordable
than the same home not built to code.
Looking at the whole picture, building energy codes provide great benefit with
relatively little cost. Thus, while climate change impacts become increasingly severe,
there is an urgent need for viable, cost-effective solutions that target key areas of great
energy consumption and pollution. With buildings consuming about 40% of energy,
building energy codes seem a suitable place to start. The process is in place and model

 

104
 

 

 

codes are continually being designed and implemented. However, there are still costs that
are keeping some states and localities from adopting up-to-date model codes. There are
also those states that have adopted the new codes, but are lacking in enforcement
resources. This goes to show that at each point along the energy code path there is room
for improvement. Much of it has to do with identifying places or areas where the costs
are too high and pouring resources that way, as is the case with photovoltaic. When we
look at the final product of building codes, namely the code-compliant house, we see that
the increase in cost that is passed onto the homeowner is repaid within a year or two. This
shows that great benefits can be achieved nationwide, with relatively little or no cost to
the consumer. Thus, the questions we should be asking are how do we get states and
localities to adopt the latest codes? How can we shift resources and bring all the states up
to date? More importantly though, how do we expand our ecological responsibilities costeffectively and how are we going to redefine our relationship with the environment,
moving forward?
These are questions that we don’t have answers for yet. However, as time
goes on, I suspect the red carpet will be rolled out for energy-efficiency. It’s clear from
this thesis that energy-efficiency measures can be cost effective and provide a substantial
payback, we now need to get our building codes on board in the best way we can. It could
be said that zero-energy homes are the goal and building codes are the path by which we
get there. Thus, it may not be long before we see building codes that require PV installs
as part of their energy code compliance or perhaps a Benchmark that requires a home to
meet a net zero balance of energy.


 

105
 

 

 

Conclusion

One could imagine a world in which the current building practices no longer
apply. Instead, all new buildings would be required to achieve a high level of efficiency
and utilize renewable energy generation so that they contribute as much energy back to
the grid as they consume. Of course, an advanced smart grid would be required and
perhaps a complete expansion of our ecological responsibilities would be needed, but it is
not impossible and in actuality, not very far off. In the face of climate change, population
growth, and unsustainable energy use, zero-energy homes offer a fast, viable, and costeffective path for moving forward into a clean-energy future. Much research has been and
is being done on the potentialities of energy-efficiency, which is at the core of the ZEH
philosophy. As money and effort are being poured into discovering new renewable
technologies and new deposits of carbon-based energy sources, energy-efficiency is
showing its face as the leader of a cleaner, more sustainable, and hopeful future. It’s not
just the built environment that is undergoing this change, but everything that requires
energy will be looked at in a new light. Once it is widely recognized that it is easier to
save energy than it is to produce it, then many objectives and motivations will change.
The objective of this thesis was to determine whether ZEHs and NZEHs are costeffective in Washington. In doing so, energy-efficient home designs on the path to net
zero were modeled for nine locations around the state. While each location showed
similar results, this was primarily due to the scope being limited to one geographical
region and, thus, a narrow range of climatic conditions. Nevertheless, it has been shown
that, depending on several factors, a complete ZEH is possible to build and is cost

 

106
 

 

 

effective. Cost-effectiveness ratios were calculated for each location thus indicating the
price per percent energy-efficiency. These figures, while not particularly useful to
consumers, could be used in developing policy or in comparing other regions ZEHs costeffectiveness. It was shown that, as energy-efficiency increases, homes become less costeffective to build. The greatest decrease in the cost-effectiveness comes at the point in
which PV begins to be implemented, with it leveling off again once the PV limit is
reached (this thesis was limited to an 8 kW system). This goes to show that the greatest
determiner of cost-effectiveness has to do with the renewable energy generation,
indicating that, as PV becomes more cost-effective, so will ZEHs.
Additionally, the return on investment was identified for each home at each
location on the path to net zero. While the cost-effectiveness ratios are a great method of
evaluation and comparison, they do little for the consumer curious about what to expect
from a home that might provide a payback. In most cases, a home will be the greatest
investment a family makes in their life. It is usually the most costly expense one incurs
but, often, has the potential to provide a return in the future, depending on several factors.
This is why it is so essential that an understanding is cultivated of what we can expect
from a home with little to no energy bills. The data in this thesis suggests that, early on,
on the path to net zero, the greatest returns will be provided below 30% energy
efficiency, with those returns declining once PV is implemented. This, of course, is due
to the high cost of PV relative the savings one receives from utility bills. However, the
ROI is highly dependent on the discount rate as well as a number of other factors that
were not considered in this thesis. For example, if conventional energy prices were to
rise, as they continually do, within the time in which someone built a ZEH, they would

 

107
 

 

 

begin to receive an even greater return on investment. Thus, ZEHs also provide an
additional benefit, one that was not quantified here, namely security from rising energy
prices. Also, as was mentioned in the analysis, under a 3% discount rate, ZEHs may not
provide a 100% payback over their lifetime. However, people value things differently
and, although a monetary quantification is usually a good standard, the benefits that come
from having a home with little to no carbon footprint will be highly valuable to some
people, especially as we observe the increasing effects of climate change.
Thus, hopefully this research serves as a starting point to encourage more
economical evaluations of what one could expect from energy-efficiency buildings,
particularly in the residential sector, where the consumer tends to drive demand. As with
any investment, people want to see what they are getting themselves into and are wary of
new and innovative concepts. This is why information can be used as a powerful
incentive to drive market changes. In the meantime, however, the government, both
federal and local, has a responsibility to drive change through building codes. As was
covered in the discussion, this is the standard method of driving change in the building
sector. Of course, there will be innovative builders at the forefront some were mentioned
in the literature review but most change will be forced and it will be slow. However, if
we are to take climate change and carbon mitigation seriously, small incremental changes
every three years are not going to do it. Perhaps multiple building codes with varying
levels of energy efficiency could be required. This way, consumers would have the
option to choose a higher energy-efficiency package without all the misinformation or
worry of what they are getting themselves into. Thus, in effect, we could create a
standard building code as well as an energy-efficient code that could then be adopted as

 

108
 

 

 

the standard after three years. Whatever happens, we need change and it needs to happen
quickly. We’ve now surpassed an atmospheric CO2 concentration of 400 ppm a first in
human history. We can’t expect to go on living the way we are, but we can’t expect
everyone to give up all of their luxuries either. Thus, compromises need to be made. We
can have the luxuries of a typical home without requiring the combustion of fossil fuels.
Since buildings have the potential to greatly reduce energy consumption and do it costeffectively, why not start here?


 

109
 

 

 

References
Alliance to Save Energy. 2010. Building Energy Code Fact Sheet.
 
<http://ase.org/resources/building-energy-codes-fact-sheet>.
Anderson, R., C. Christensen, and S. Horowitz. 2006. Analysis of residential system
strategies targeting least-cost solutions leading to net zero-energy homes.
ASHRAE Transactions 112:330–341.
Anderson, R., and D. Roberts. 2008. Maximizing residential energy savings: net zeroenergy home technology pathways. TP-550-44547.DOE. NREL. Golden, CO,
US.
Attia, S. G., and A. De Herde. 2011. Early design simulation tools for net zero-energy
buildings: a comparison of ten tools. 12th Conference of IBPSA. Sydney,
Australia. November, 2011.
Attia, S., E. Gratia, A. De Herde, and J. L. M. Hensen. 2012. Simulation-based decision
support tool for early stages of zero-energy building design. Energy and Buildings
49:2–15.
Bergey, D., and K. Uneo. 2011. New England net zero production houses. Building
Science Information. Research Report 1303.
<http://www.buildingscience.com/documents/reports/rr-1103-new-england-net
zero-production-houses/view>.
Bianchi, M. V. 2011. Challenges and opportunities to achieve 50% energy savings in
homes: national laboratory white papers. GO-102011-3242. DOE.


 

110
 

 

 

Brown, C., Glicksman, and M. Lehar. 2010. Toward zero-energy buildings: optimized for
energy use and cost. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Fourth Conference of
IBPSA. New York City, NY. August, 2010.
Carrilho da Graça, G., A. Augusto, and M. M. Lerer. 2012. Solar powered net zeroenergy houses for southern Europe: feasibility study. Solar Energy 86:634–646.
Christensen, C., Anderson, Ren, Horowitz, Scott, Courtney, Adam, and Spencer, Justin.
2006. BEopt software for building energy optimization: features and capabilities.
TP-550-39929. U.S. DOE. NREL. Boulder, CO, US.
Danny S., P. 2009. Very low energy homes in the United States: perspectives on
performance from measured data. Energy and Buildings 41:512–520.
Deru, M., and P. Torcellini. 2006. Source energy and emission factors for energy use in
buildings. TP-550-38617. DOE. NREL. Golden, CO, US.
DOE and EIA. 2012. State Electricity Profiles 2010. 0348(01)2. DOE. EIA. Washington,
D.C., US. <http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/pdf/sep2010.pdf.>.
DSIRE. 2012. Renewable energy cost recovery incentive payment program.
<http://www.dsireusa.org/incentives/incentive.cfm?Incentive_Code=WA27F>.
EPA. 2006. Clean Energy- Environment Guide to Action. 430-R-06-001. EPA. OAP.
Washington, D.C. US <http://www.epa.gov/statelocalclimate/resources/actionguide.html>.
Farhar, B., and T. Coburn. 2008. A new market paradigm for zero-energy homes: a
comparative case study. Environment. 50:18–32.
Gray, M., and J. Zarnikau. 2011. Getting to Zero: Green Building and Net Zero-Energy
Homes. Butterworth-Heinemann, Boston.

 

111
 

 

 

Hendron, R., and C. Engebrecht. 2010. Building America house simulation protocols.
GO-102010-3141.U.S. DOE. NREL.
Houser, T. 2009. The economics of energy efficiency in buildings. Policy Brief 09-17.
Peterson Institute for international Economics, Washington, D.C, US.
Hernandez, P., and P. Kenny. 2010. From net energy to zero-energy buildings: defining
life cycle zero-energy buildings (LC-ZEB). Energy and Buildings 42:815–821.
IPCC. 2007. AR4 SYR synthesis report summary for policymakers - observed changes in
climate and their effects.
<http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/syr/en/spms1.html.>.
Koch, D. C., W. J. Hutzel, J. M. Kutch, and E. A. Holt. 2011. Toward a zero-energy
home: applying Swiss building practices/attitudes to U.S. residential construction.
Journal of Technology Studies 37:18–26.
Kolokotsa, D., D. Rovas, E. Kosmatopoulos, and K. Kalaitzakis. 2011. A roadmap
towards intelligent net zero- and positive-energy buildings. Solar Energy
85:3067–3084.
Levin, H. M., and P. J. McEwan. 2001. Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: Methods and
Applications. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Lopez, H. 2008. The social discount rate: estimates of 9 Latin American countries. Policy
Research Working Paper WPS4639. The World Bank. Latin American and
Caribbean Region.
Madeja, R., and S. Moujaes. 2008. Comparison of simulation and experimental data of a
zero-energy home in an arid climate. Journal of Energy Engineering 134:102–
108.

 

112
 

 

 

Marszal, A. J., P. Heiselberg, J. S. Bourrelle, E. Musall, K. Voss, I. Sartori, and A.
Napolitano. 2011. Zero-energy buildings – a review of definitions and calculation
methodologies. Energy and Buildings 43:971–979.
Miller, W., and L. Buys. 2012. Anatomy of a sub-tropical positive energy home (PEH).
Solar Energy 86:231–241.
Mississippi Development Authority. 2013. Energy Codes Create Better Homes.
<http://www.mississippi.org/assets/docs/energy/homeowner-faq.pdf>.
Norton, P., and C. Christensen. 2008. Performance results from a cold climate case study
for affordable zero-energy homes. ASHRAE Transactions 114:218–229.
Osmani, M., and A. O’Reilly. 2009. Feasibility of zero carbon homes in England by
2016: a house builder’s perspective. Building and Environment 44:1917–1924.
Sartori, I., A. Napolitano, and K. Voss. 2012. Net zero-energy buildings: a consistent
definition framework. Energy and Buildings 48:220–232.
Srinivasan, R. S., W. W. Braham, D. E. Campbell, and C. D. Curcija. 2012. Re(De)fining
net zero energy: renewable emergy balance in environmental building design.
Building and Environment 47:300–315.
Stern, N. 2006. The Stern Review Report on the Economics of Climate Change. HM
Treasury. London, England.
Talapatra, A. 2009. Implementing energy efficiency in building codes based on the
America clean energy and security act of 2009. Federation of American
Scientists. Washington, D.C, US.


 

113
 

 

 

Tans, P., and R. Keeling. 2013. Recent monthly mean CO2 at Mauna Loa. NOAA/ESRL,
Scripps Institution of Oceanography. <www.esrl.noaa.gov/gmd/ccgg/trends/,
scrippsco2.ucsd.edu/>.
Torcellini, P., S. Pless, M. Deru, and D. Crawley. 2006. Zero-energy buidlings: a critical
look at the definition. ACEEE Summer Study, Pacfic Grove, California. US.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2007.American Fact Finder. <http://factfinder2.census.gov>

 
DOE. 2010. Building Energy Codes 101: An Introduction.
PNNL-SA-70586. <http://www.energycodes.gov/>
DOE. 2012. National energy and cost savings for new
single-and multifamily homes: a comparison of the 2006, 2009, and 2012
editions of the IECC. PNNL-21329. DOE. Washington, D.C. US
<http://www.energycodes.gov/sites/default/files/documents/NationalResidentialC
ostEffectiveness.pdf>
DOE. 2013. Building Energy Codes Program. <http://www.energycodes.gov/>
CDC. 2013. Climate and Health Program. Health Effects.
<http://www.cdc.gov/climateandhealth/effects/default.htm>
EPA. 2006. National Action Plan for Energy Efficiency Report. DOE. EPA.
http://www.epa.gov/cleanenergy/energy-programs/suca/resources.html
EPA. 2012. Consumer Energy Efficiency Fact <http://www.epa.gov/cleanenergy/energyprograms/suca/resources.html>
U.S. House.1992. 102nd Congress. H.R.776.ENR. Energy Policy Act of 1992
U.S. House. 2009. 11th Congress. H.R.111-5.ARRA. American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act of 2009

 

114
 

 

 

Verbruggen, A., M. A. Marchohi, and B. Janssens. 2011. The anatomy of investing in
energy efficient buildings. Energy and Buildings 43:905–914.
Wang, L., J. Gwilliam, and P. Jones. 2009. Case study of zero-energy house design in
UK. Energy and Buildings 41:1215–1222.
Wholey, J. S., Harry P. Hatry, and K. E. Newcomer. 2010. Handbook of Practical
Program Evaluation, 3rd edition. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA.
Zhu, L., R. Hurt, D. Correa, and R. Boehm. 2009. Comprehensive energy and economic
analyses on a zero-energy house versus a conventional house. Energy 34:1043–
1053


 

115
 

 

 


 

116